RBA Annual Conference – 2003 It Takes More Than a Bubble to Become Japan Adam Posen[1]

Japan's extended economic stagnation since its stock market peaked on December 29, 1989 has prompted a series of investigations, recommendations, and self-examinations both in Japan and abroad. For monetary policy, two aspects of the situation have attracted particular attention. One is the ability or inability of a central bank to successfully raise the price level and inflation expectations when the nominal interest rate is at zero and the banking system is reluctant to lend. The other is the appropriate response of a central bank to an asset-price bubble: whether the central bank can or should try to ‘prick’ such a bubble when it is expanding, and how the central bank should cope with the economic aftermath of such a bubble bursting. This paper will consider the latter set of issues as raised by the Japanese bubble.[2]

The topic is of more than retrospective or theoretical concern. As Figure 1 plotting the time path of the Japanese Nikkei and US S&P 500 stock averages relative to peak shows, in recent years the American equity market had just about an identical boom, and so far a slightly milder bust, to that of the Japanese market – and the Japanese and American real estate markets both followed similar paths at about a two-year lag to stocks (Figure 2). These are hardly the only examples. A series of applied research studies done at international financial institutions has shown that there have been a great number of asset-price booms and busts, if not definitively bubbles, and these are often associated with negative economic outcomes.[3] Small wonder that, in the wake of the IT and telecoms boom, many countries today are asking themselves ‘Who will be the next Japan?’[4]

Figure 1: Stock Market Performance
Figure 2: Housing Prices

The main argument of this paper is that it takes more than a bubble to become Japan. While asset-price booms and even busts are not uncommon, Japan's Great Recession is, and it was not the bubble and its burst that produced this outcome. That point may not be especially controversial to those well familiar with Japan's plight. The loud concern expressed in influential parts of both the press and the official sector with regards to the implications of the US asset-price boom (for example, in editorials of The Economist and the Financial Times), however, seems to say that the destiny of any bubble economy is an extended recession. Some Japanese politicians and pundits have seized upon the post-crash downturn in the US economy to get their own back for the years of unremitting lecturing by their American counterparts about economic policy; they suggest that the criticisms of Japanese policy were, if not unfounded, at least coming home to roost. All these participants in the discussion would lay the responsibility for this destiny of recession at the failure of the central banks involved to take action against the rise of bubbles.

These concerns and comments, while understandable, are not supported by study of the Japanese case. Monetary policy clearly was (and remains) a contributing factor to Japan's stagnation, but it was not disregard of asset prices either on their way up or of their effects on the way down which produced this outcome. Spirited academic debates about whether central banks should directly target asset prices, either as part of an inflation-targeting framework or not, need a different case on which to hook their analyses.[5] As I will argue, the Bank of Japan (BOJ) should have been able to tighten policy more quickly in the late 1980s and loosen policy more quickly in the early 1990s without any particular reference to asset-price movements – and in any event, monetary policy might well have been unable to stop those movements. Negative developments in the Japanese economy after the bubble were hardly driven by the fall in asset values, but rather by other problems in the Japanese economy (including overly tight monetary policy itself). Comparative analysis broadly of other recent cases of asset-price booms and, in more depth, of developments in the US in parallel (relative to its asset-price peak), support my conclusion that a primary concern for monetary policy should be how to encourage restructuring in the aftermath of a boom, not the boom itself.

The paper is comprised of five sections. First, it considers whether monetary ease in the 1980s caused Japan's bubble, as is often suggested. I conclude that the bubble was just as likely to occur whatever monetary policy within reason would have done, drawing on both a new cross-national consideration of the monetary policy asset-price linkage and a re-examination of what actually occurred in Japan 1985–1990. Second, it asks whether the bubble's burst caused Japan's Great Recession. In fact, I argue, Japan's recession of 1990–1994 was far milder than is commonly recognised, and easily explicable by factors outside of the asset-price decline – only a combination of policy mistakes turned this normal recession into the extended stagnation we now fear, and thereby gave time for the asset-price declines to have large real effects. This is borne out by cross-national investigation suggesting the frequency of extended downturns following asset booms is relatively low.

Third, the paper compares the post-bubble response of the US and Japanese economies to ask whether the bubble itself impeded restructuring. The data paint a picture of very different responses in the two economies, suggesting that the bubble itself is not a sufficient cause of real-side disruption. Fourth, it looks at whether monetary policy in Japan could have encouraged restructuring. I find some evidence in support of the view that part of the reason for the difference in adjustment between the US and Japan is attributable to differences in monetary response. Finally, I set out what central bankers should learn from Japan's bubble, emphasising the benefits of a more thoughtful approach to assessing potential growth and of easing rapidly in the face of asset-price declines.

1. Did Monetary Laxity in Japan Cause the Bubble?

As noted, the belief is widespread that excessive laxity of Japanese monetary policy in 1986–1989 caused the bubble in Japanese equity and real estate prices.[6] BOJ officials for the last 13 years have bemoaned this fact, vowing not to repeat the mistake (e.g., Hayami (2000a, 2000b); Yamaguchi (1999)). Outside observers of a more monetarist bent have largely agreed with this lesson, thanking their central bankers for being able to resist pressures for undue ease (e.g., Siebert (2000)). And both academics and market pundits have chimed in as well, attributing the bubble to inaction by the Bank of Japan (e.g., Jinushi, Kuroki and Miyao (2000); Nakamae (2000, 2001)). For some the message is a reaffirmation of the importance of central bank independence, since the BOJ is thought to have succumbed to pressure from the Ministry of Finance (MOF) for ease;[7] for others the lesson is that central banks should take asset prices into account when setting policy. Either way, according to this common view, the bubble arose, or at least grew large, because of excessive liquidity.

This claim that monetary policy caused Japan's bubble, however, should not be taken for granted. We need to decide whether excessive monetary ease was a sufficient condition for the Japanese bubble (‘if sustained monetary ease, then a bubble occurs’), a necessary condition for the Japanese bubble (‘if a bubble occurs, then there must have been prior monetary ease’), or both. The theoretical foundations for such claims turn out to be little more than ones of coincident timing – in Japan in the second half of the 1980s, money supply was growing, velocity was declining, and no increase showed up in wholesale or consumer prices, so the contemporaneous growth in real estate and equity prices must have been the result of this liquidity increase. Yet, this is a rather tenuous link to make. As Japan itself has demonstrated in the last few years, one can have all these conditions present (expanding money supply, declining velocity, no effect on the price level) and still see no increasing trend in asset prices. Without some forward-looking expectations on the part of investors that returns will be rising relative to base interest rates, that profits will be growing, there will be no buying of real estate or equities.

For monetary policy to be the source of a bubble, the relative price of one part of the economy (here financial and real estate assets) has to be pumped up by a blunt instrument that usually affects all prices in the economy.[8] And it has to do so in such a way that the relative price shift either does not raise expectations of a countervailing shift in monetary policy in the near future (which relies on strange notions of what the imputed future income from increasing land and stock prices will generate), or is expected to only be affected by monetary policy on the upside but not on the down (which there is no reason to believe, if liquidity is the source of the relative price shift in the first place). Either way, this has to take place when we know both analytically and empirically that the relationship between a policy of low interest rates or high money growth and equity or real estate prices is actually indeterminate over time.[9] Of course, one can resolve this logical tension by positing that the investors have unrealistic expectations about monetary policy. Okina and Shiratsuka (2003) and Shiratsuka (1999) do so, for example, by characterising with some justification Japanese investors in the bubble years as believing unduly in low interest rates over a decade or longer horizon. Then, however, it is the expectations of investors which are driving the asset-price process, not the actions of monetary policy. In that case, any monetary policy short of starving the economy of credit could give rise to a boom, and a boom can arise even without excessive ease.

Before evaluating with respect to the Japanese case the merits of this claim versus the more common assumption that monetary laxity causes booms, it is worth pointing out that neither claim has been established with respect to bubbles or asset-price booms in general. If this supposed causal link between monetary laxity and the Japanese bubble is not as apparent in other known cases of asset-price booms, then there clearly is more at work in the Japanese case than just monetary ease. To examine this question, we take a list of asset-price booms in the OECD economies and match them up with a new dataset created to offer simple indicators of loose monetary conditions. Thus, the approach is pseudo-epidemiological, generating a list of cases that satisfy one, both, or neither condition at the same time. First the hypothesis ‘If sustained monetary ease, then an asset-price boom appears’ is examined, then the converse, ‘If a boom appears, then there was prior ease’.

The list of asset-price booms is taken from Bordo and Jeanne (2002), who identify them when the three-year moving average of the growth rate in the asset price under scrutiny falls outside a confidence interval of long-run historical average growth rate plus a multiple of the average volatility of all asset-price growth rates in the sample.[10] Looking at 15 countries (including Japan) over 1970–2000 for industrial share prices and 1970–1998 for residential property prices, they identify 18 booms in property prices and 24 booms in share prices (Table A1 lists them). For our purposes, this generates a list of booms independent of our markers of monetary ease and, in the next section, of deflation.

Identifying periods of monetary ease would appear to be much harder. As the ample monetary economics literature demonstrates, estimating the effect of monetary policy on the economy at a given moment, or assessing whether or not interest rates should be raised or lowered (given some welfare function) is contentious. It is clearly beyond the scope of this paper to generate country- and period-specific assessments of the relative looseness of monetary policy to go with the list of observed booms. For the purposes of examining the link between monetary ease and booms, however, a simple approach seems justified. In the discussion of monetary policy with respect to perceived bubbles, particularly but not just with regards to Japan, there is usually the sense that it took significant sustained ease to cause the bubble – booms do not seem to pop up frequently enough to be associated with minor mistakes of overly easy monetary policy. In particular, bubbles are usually thought to be associated with long credit booms (Borio and Lowe 2002). If either short periods of monetary ease or small degrees of ease are enough to generate or support booms on their own, that would seem to imply either that booms should be even more frequent than they are, or that the link between ease and booms is indeed rather tenuous.

So for our investigations we utilise two broadly applicable measures of monetary ease: first, whether the central bank's real overnight or instrument interest rate is less than 1 per cent for a sustained period; second, whether growth in a credit aggregate greatly exceeds the aggregate's average growth rate for a sustained period. The second criterion uses a threshold of whether M3 (or appropriate broad money measure by country) year-ended growth exceeds the average rate by one standard deviation of that aggregate's growth rate.[11] The idea is that for any functioning economy with real returns, a 1 per cent or less real interest rate must be considered loose (versus any reasonable estimate of the natural rate of interest), whereas for any given country the baseline for credit growth has to be country-specific reflecting local credit markets, velocity trends, etc. A sustained period of ease is defined as two or more quarters in a row exceeding the M3 growth or below the real overnight rate threshold.[12] Again, the idea is to create a list of periods of monetary ease of sufficient heft to be potential causes for asset-price booms.

We create a list of these periods for the same 15 OECD countries over the same time period as in the Bordo and Jeanne (2002) sample, and find 38 periods of monetary ease by the M3 criterion and 11 periods of monetary ease by the real interest rate criterion. We see whether asset-price booms occurred within 36 months of the end of one of these periods of monetary ease. The three-year time-horizon is chosen both to fit with the outer limit of the usual assumed lag before the effects of monetary policy are fully felt, and with the three-year moving averages that are used to define the boom periods. If the boom begins within the period of monetary ease, that is ‘credited’ to the ease, allowing for the possibility of forward-looking asset markets somehow seeing that monetary ease will be sustained and responding euphorically. This very large window should err on the side of associating many booms with periods of ease, even if the ease had just started, or if the ease was fading into the past.

Table 1 presents the results in response to the question, ‘If ease, then boom?’ The results do not support the popular image of sustained monetary ease being a sufficient condition for a boom. Of 38 periods of ease identified by the M3 criterion, only 12 resulted in share-price booms, and 12 in property booms (the lists are not identical); of 11 periods of sustained ease by the interest rate criterion, no booms followed within 36 months. Of course, some of these periods of monetary ease were in response to contemporaneous or forecast times of slow growth or low inflation, and might not be expected to generate much in the way of asset-price booms during those periods. Yet, run-ups in asset prices often begin well ahead of actual economic recoveries, and here would be counted if they began within 42 months of the monetary ease – a longer period than most recessions. In any event, the absence of any booms in response to low real interest rates would seem to put the focus on credit market conditions more narrowly, but even by that criterion there fewer than one-in-three periods of significantly above average credit expansion are followed by booms.

Table 1: If Monetary Easing, then Boom?
Sustained monetary easing (M3 growth)
Total: 38 periods
Industrial share price boom within 36 months
12 booms
Sustained monetary easing (r<1%)
Total: 10 periods
0 booms
Sustained monetary easing (M3 growth)
Total: 38 periods
Residential property price boom within 36 months
12 booms
Sustained monetary easing (r<1%)
Total: 10 periods
0 booms
Note: Monetary easing sustained is defined as a period of two quarters or more (or 3/4, 5/6, etc) during which the real interest rate was less than 1 or M3 (or equivalent broad money measure) growth was greater than the country's mean plus one standard deviation.

The idea that monetary ease alone is a sufficient condition for asset-price booms might appear to be something of a straw man, though it is one that is often put forward without question in the discussions of the Japanese bubble. Perhaps this confusion is because those speaking about Japan actually subscribe to the idea of sustained monetary ease as a necessary, not a sufficient, condition for a boom to occur – if an asset-price boom, then there must have been prior ease. In other words, on this hypothesis, while there can be periods of ease which do not result in bubbles, there are no bubbles that did not result from monetary ease. This relates closely to the idea of central banks ‘pricking’ asset-price bubbles, that interest rate increases somehow remove the loose credit conditions on which the bubble is predicated (an idea we examine in the next section).

Utilising the same list of booms and periods of monetary ease we consider this possibility in Table 2. We look at two possibilities, that ease must have preceded the start of the boom, or that at a minimum there must have been ease during the boom.[13] Neither elicits much support from the data – for property and share-price booms, fewer than one-third of them were either preceded by or accompanied by sustained ease in credit growth; none of the share-price booms were preceded or accompanied by sustained ease on these criteria.

Table 2: If Boom, then Prior Monetary Ease?
Total number of booms Within 36 months
prior to start?
Ease during boom
(except last quarter)?
r<1% M3 greater than mean plus one SD r<1% M3 greater than mean plus one SD
Residential property price booms 18 0 6   0 6
Industrial share price booms 24 0 8   1 6
Note: Monetary easing sustained is defined as a period of two quarters or more (or 3/4, 5/6, etc) during which the real interest rate was less than 1 or M3 (or equivalent broad money measure) growth was greater than the country's mean plus one standard deviation.

The results are therefore far from supportive of monetary laxity as either a necessary or a sufficient condition for asset-price booms, at least with regards to the advanced OECD economies since 1970. The direct association often drawn between the Bank of Japan's monetary policy stance in the late 1980s and the Japanese bubble therefore bears closer scrutiny. In short, there is more to the story than just that the BOJ did not raise rates in time. The (Japanese) textbook version of the story is that international pressure upon Japan from the United States led to too much ease from the BOJ, and that ease led to the bubble.[14] Japan had come out of the second oil shock, carefully closing its public deficits and managing money for price stability. At the time, protectionist pressures were mounting in the US Congress due to the large US trade deficits and the rise of the Reagan-Volcker dollar. First in the Plaza Accord of September 22, 1985, and then (after additional bilateral pressures from the US government) in the Louvre Agreement of February 20, 1987, the Japanese government agreed to stimulate domestic growth and help manage an appreciation of the yen against the dollar.

Under direction from the MOF, the BOJ began to make interest rate cuts in January 1986, starting with an overnight rate of 5.0 per cent. By the time of the last cut three years later, the BOJ had cut its overnight rate to 1.0 per cent. These rate cuts took place against a background of financial liberalisation in the mid 1980s that had the BOJ placing greater reliance on its interest rate instrument in implementing monetary policy, and less on reserve and moral suasion measures upon banks. Meanwhile, the MOF did not wish to imperil its hard-won budgetary consolidation by engaging in expansionary fiscal policy, so the burden of stimulus fell totally on the BOJ. The yen appreciated from a low of 240 per US dollar to 125 per US dollar, inducing the short-lived Endaka (high-yen) recession of 1985–1986. The Heisei boom that we think of as the bubble years began shortly thereafter. No obvious increases in the CPI or WPI arose for the remainder of the decade, and most private sector forecasts were for continued low inflation (Ahearne et al 2002). The ‘Black Monday’ US stock market crash of October 1987 provided another reason for the BOJ to keep interest rates low. In this version of the story, the issue is whether the BOJ could have raised interest rates some time in 1988, and in so doing have pricked the bubble.

Yet, none of this explains why there should have been a bubble in Japanese equity and real estate markets. Something had to transform the easy monetary policy into asset-price appreciation rather than either more general price pressures or sustainable growth. Again, the sole argument for blaming monetary policy seems to be one of timing. Even that, however, does not hold up well. Land prices were already rising before the Plaza Accord, let alone the full force of the BOJ's rate cuts: one common index shows a 12.7 per cent increase in FY1984 and a 28.9 per cent increase in FY1985. And the run-up in stocks began even when the Endaka experience was fresh in people's minds but the only policy commitment of the BOJ, not by choice, was supposedly to keep the yen on an upward trend. If the decision to cut rates in 1986–1989 was truly a political decision in response to US pressures on the MOF, and the MOF on the BOJ – as reported upon in the press and clearly grumbled about by BOJ officials – why was the BOJ's frustrated case for tighter policy not persuasive to the bond markets? Surely, if it were clear that the BOJ were violating its normal policy priorities due to obvious international pressure, the idea that such low rates would be sustainable without any effect on inflation or medium-term growth would have been discounted. The fault for the asset-price increases seems to lie in the unrealistic expectations of participants in a bubble, not in Japanese monetary ease.

Let us turn the question around: should the BOJ have believed in the macroeconomics of the Heisei boom in the second half of the 1980s? Or should they have been in a position to discount this story? The debate among monetary economists over this period usually is cast as whether or not a central bank can read asset prices any better than financial markets, and can they assess the evaluation of equities. As the Japanese case of the late 1980s illustrates, this debate is misfocused. Whatever the state of asset prices, central banks have to assess the potential growth rate of the economy they oversee, and this macroeconomic assessment can be done largely independently of any specific relative prices in the economy (Kuttner 1994; de Brouwer 1998). For Japan in 1987–1991, output was 2 per cent a year above trend, and 1988 showed the highest growth rate (7 per cent) seen since the mid 1970s.

Meanwhile, just looking at overall market averages, the stock and bond prices implied either 15 or more years of low interest rates or a massive drop in the risk premium (Ito and Iwaisako 1995). Could a significant drop in the risk premium be held credible for aging Japanese savers, given well-known demographic trends and savings behaviour? Alternatively, how could interest rates be expected to stay low indefinitely if the boom's euphoria was based on a real increase in the potential rate of output – and therefore of the economy's natural rate of interest – over the long run? As Figure 3 shows with regard to Japanese labour productivity, the apparent surge in productivity in the late 1980s was something to be suspicious about. Given limited deregulation, the end of catch-up growth, and the absence of any new technological revolution, what would justify a near-doubling of productivity growth from its around 3 per cent average of 1979–1987?[15] What precedent was there for a 2 per cent jump in trend productivity anywhere except emerging markets making the great leap as Japan already had in the 1950s?[16]

Figure 3: Japan – Labour Productivity Growth

Figure 4 underlines the reason for scepticism by comparing the investment/GDP ratio of the US and Japan against time from stock market peak: where US investment went from 15.1 per cent to 17.9 per cent over the course of the bubble (up about a fifth), the Japanese investment/GDP ratio increased by nearly a third (from 20 per cent to over 26 per cent), from a higher initial level, for an economy with an already high capital-output ratio. The law of diminishing marginal returns should not have been expected to be withdrawn.

Figure 4: Nominal Investment Share

In short, the BOJ could have decided to tighten policy in the 1980s without any reference to asset prices beyond the most general evaluation of interest rate expectations. It was not lack of explicit attention to rises in asset prices that led monetary policy astray. No expectations based on a reasonable evaluation of monetary policy could have supported these macroeconomic assumptions embodied in the overall asset market. Kuttner and Posen (2003) establish that for any of a wide range of potential output estimates – using real-time available information and varying in method, but never explicitly including asset prices – the BOJ would have normally been expected to raise rates some time in 1987–1988. Of course, even if interest rates had been increased, it is not evident that alone would have ‘popped’ the bubble.

One could try to restore the link between the Japanese asset-price bubble and monetary policy by asserting that a firm belief in ongoing pressure from the US for yen appreciation in response to the US' endemic trade deficits, rather than actual faith in the potential output measures implied, was what underlay the belief in monetary ease and thus the boom. Perhaps that would have been more rational than belief in the bubble per se. As Ronald McKinnon and Kenichi Ohno have shown, however, at least theoretically a long-term expectation of sustained yen appreciation will result in deflationary expectations (including of asset prices) in Japan.[17] The point here though is that even if the monetary ease were held to be sustainable due to the US pressure rather than false economic assumptions, that too would require false economic assumptions by the market participants, well beyond those about whatever the BOJ might do, to result in the sustained asset-price rise. So there is no way to square this circle of the bubble somehow logically resting on expectations of future Japanese monetary policy. The bubble was independent of them.

We should turn instead to the obvious non-monetary factors in the creation of the Japanese bubble. These financial developments are both well within the usual remit of a central bank's surveillance, and logical justification for why the unrealistic expectations of bubble participants were fed irrespective of monetary policy. As set out in Hoshi and Kashyap (2000), Cargill, Hutchison and Ito (2000), and Posen and Mikitani (2000), there is a consensus view among economists on how partial financial deregulation in Japan in the 1980s led to a lending boom.[18] Japan's banks lost their best corporate customers after the liberalisation of securities markets allowed large firms to reduce their cost of capital by seeking direct financing. The banks' ability to move into new lines of business was still partially constrained by regulation, and their franchise value was declining, yet they retained the same large amount of loanable funds due to deposit insurance. The ‘Convoy’ system of financial supervision, which equated banking system stability with no closure of banks, kept overcapacity in the system, leading to low profits and under-capitalisation, increasing the desire to take risks with taxpayer-insured deposits.

As a result, Japanese banks made a huge shift into lending to small- and medium-enterprises (SMEs), increasing that share of their loan portfolios from 42 per cent in 1983 to 57 per cent in 1989, while their loan portfolios expanded by more than half (see Figure 5). The banks nearly doubled their overall lending in selected sectors favourable to the SMEs.[19] Companies hold substantial real estate in Japan, and used this as collateral of rising worth to borrow more; households also took advantage of rising home prices and declining lending standards (mortgage limits rose from 65 per cent of home value on average to 100 per cent on the assumption that land prices would go up).[20] Two additional indicators of this lending/real estate boom arising out of the partial deregulation/ongoing deposits dynamic were the increase in Japanese banks lending directly to firms in the real estate sector, from 6 per cent of total lending in 1983 to more than 12 per cent in 1989, and the extreme pressure on the long-term credit banks that were most dependent on the borrowing of major corporations (as documented in Shimizu (2000)).

Figure 5: Commercial Bank Assets as a Share of GDP

It is easy to draw the chain of causality from improved access to capital for both large and small business, due to rising collateral values as well as deregulation and shifts in lending standards, to rising expectations of profits and stock prices. And in Japan's system of cross-shareholdings and banks owning significant share portfolios in borrower firms, these effects are amplified through increases in bank capital. Some belief in the rising value of land does underlie this dynamic, but once that is given, one can understand the emergence of a bubble in both stock and asset prices with no reference to monetary ease whatsoever. For comparison, remember that the analogous dynamic seen in the US savings and loan industry took place in the early and mid 1980s, hardly a time of monetary ease.

So how did the BOJ monetary policy respond to this structural source of asset-price increases? The evaluation tends to turn on whether the BOJ should have raised rates in 1988 instead of waiting until 1989, and how much they should have raised rates.[21] This is often cast as a dispute over the sufficiency of inflation targeting as a guideline for monetary policy-making, without explicitly taking asset prices into account. This dispute turns on the definition of a policy rule for the inflation-targeting central bank, and the information content of asset prices for inflation and output beyond factors normally considered. As I have argued here and (on an empirical basis) in Kuttner and Posen (2003), however, the proper perspective on potential output in Japan in the second half of the 1980s on its own terms would have led to rate increases in any usual forward-looking policy rule. The issue of whether asset prices should or should not explicitly enter the central bank's target is moot (at least for Japan).[22]

In terms of the practice of monetary policy in the real world, inflation targeting is not about simple policy rules and what data enter them, it is about communication and accountability.[23] And it is with regard to communication and accountability that inflation targeting is indeed relevant for the behaviour of the BOJ in the late 1980s, as well as for other central banks facing asset-price booms. Figure 6 shows the delay, then the more rapid and steep increase in the BOJ's overnight interest rate, followed by relative slowness in cutting its overnight rate, in comparison to the Federal Reserve response (relative to their respective economies' asset-price peaks). The difference in the movements of the two economies' real effective exchange rate (plotted in Figure 7), another determinant of monetary conditions, was not enough to explain this divergence. The BOJ ultimately was slow to raise rates and then raised them high and kept them high, because around 1987 it radically increased its relative weight on inflation versus output goals, and discounted the information from developments in the real economy.[24]

Figure 6: Nominal Overnight Interest Rate
Figure 7: Real Effective Exchange Rate

It is ironic that the BOJ began approximating an ‘inflation nutter’, in Mervyn King's sense of the term, in the late 1980s, in contrast to the frequently told story about the Louvre Agreement and political pressures (not to mention Black Monday) causing monetary laxity. Yamaguchi (1999) indicates as much by saying that it would have been politically impossible to raise rates earlier than when the BOJ did without evidence of inflationary pressures – precisely when information from the potential growth side was offering that evidence. Had the BOJ been under an inflation-targeting regime, the sole focus on inflation would have been revealed to the public and (one hopes) reversed; conversely, had the BOJ had an inflation-targeting communications framework to draw upon, they could have conveyed to the public the inflationary pressures that were evident, even if not showing up yet in the WPI or CPI. In any event, the monetary ease in Japan in 1987–1989 was not the result of the bubble not being taken into account, just as the bubble was not the result of the monetary ease.

2. Did the Bubble Cause Japan's Deflation or Stagnation?

Just as with monetary ease and the bubble, the idea that the bursting of Japan's bubble caused the economy's stagnation through at least the first half of the 1990s is widespread and often taken for granted. Some interested market participants go so far as to say that just about everything bad that has happened to the Japanese economy is due to the decline in asset prices, and that decline's direct effect on corporate and household balance sheets (e.g., Koo (2003)). Bank of Japan officials make less extreme claims, but do attribute much of the ongoing difficulties in the Japanese economy to the bubble's burst.[25] And some economic researchers, notably Bayoumi (2001), give pride of place to the balance-sheet effects on the banking system as an explanation for the decline in Japanese output. The only outspoken opposition to this claim is usually from those who argue, from a real business cycle framework (e.g., Hayashi and Prescott (2000)), that Japan's economy is in a systemic decline.

This claim that the bubble's burst caused Japan's stagnation, like the claim about monetary ease and the bubble, is overdue for re-examination. Obviously, no serious macroeconomist who allows balance sheets, let alone credit markets and nominal rigidities, to play a meaningful role in her economic models would deny that significant declines in asset prices can have real effects. That is why macroeconomics was born as a field in response to the Great Depression. The economic effects of asset-price declines are likely to be particularly felt in the case when nominal debt and collateral interact with the provision of credit predominantly through a banking system (Bernanke 1983; Kiyotaki and Moore 1997). Overhangs of distressed real estate and a credit crunch for SMEs that are cut out of bank lending are certainly aspects of some of the worst recessions. For Japan, though, the issue is more empirical – when did the bubble's burst have its effect, how large was that effect, and what other factors were going on at the time in Japan. I will argue that observers tend to conflate the post-1999 years of deflation and stagnation in Japan with the bubble of the late 1980s, leaving out the fact that a relatively normal if not mild recession and viable recovery took place in between. Japan, it turns out, is not the poster child for asset-price declines causing recession, we have to look elsewhere.

As recent research has begun to uncover, not all asset-price crashes have significant negative effects on macroeconomic outcomes, despite the availability of plausible channels for transmission of the shock. Mishkin and White (2002), for example, consider 15 US stock market crashes in the last 100 years, and find that 8 generated ‘some’ or ‘severe’ financial distress, of which only a few were followed by sharp contractions. We know that asset-price busts are far more common than periods of prolonged stagnation let alone deflation like Japan has seen. If the supposed direct link between the Japanese bubble bursting and persistent sub-potential growth is not as apparent in other known cases of asset-price booms, then there clearly is more at work in the Japanese case than just the bubble's impact itself.

Similarly to the previous section's consideration of the link between ease and bubbles, we begin examining the link between bubbles and deflation by establishing a cross-national benchmark. For the 15 OECD countries in our 1970–2000 sample, we identify periods of sustained deflation, where either the wholesale or consumer price index declined for two or more quarters in succession. Deflation in WPI turns out to be surprisingly common, with 73 cases in our sample (full list of cases is given in the Appendix). Sustained consumer price deflation is significantly less common – only 9 cases counting Japan at the end of the 1990s – but is still more frequent than many people may realise. Following the format of Tables 1 and 2, we use our list of cases of deflation and (from Bordo and Jeanne (2002)) of ends of asset-price booms to see whether such bubble bursts are necessary or sufficient for deflation to arise.[26]

Table 3 reports the results for the question whether an asset-price burst is sufficient to cause deflation. The sample is again split between 18 residential property and 24 industrial share-price bursts, and then between CPI and WPI deflation periods. The cases of bursts are sorted into whether the onset of a sustained deflation (on a given price index) occurred within 36 months of the burst. Of the 9 cases of CPI deflation, only 2 were preceded by equity bursts within 36 months prior. Notably Japan is not one of those (more than 8 years between the burst and the onset of deflation), and none of the deflationary periods were preceded by property bursts. For WPI deflation, there is clearly more of a connection, but interestingly stronger on the share price (17/24 bursts followed by deflation within 36 months) than on residential property (8/18), even though Borio, Furfine and Lowe (2001) and Bordo and Jeanne (2002) both find evidence that residential property bursts tend to have larger effects. Table 4 tackles the converse, whether an asset-price burst is necessary to cause deflation. The procedure is reversed, first identifying the cases of CPI and WPI inflation, and then seeing how many of them had a burst (either share or property price) within 36 months prior, and gives the same picture.

Table 3: If Boom, then Deflation?
CPI deflation
within 36 months
No CPI deflation WPI deflation
within 36 months
No WPI deflation
Residential property price burst
18 0 18 8 10
Industrial share price burst
24 2 22 17 7
Note: Deflation is defined as two quarters or more (or 3/4, 5/6, etc) of negative change in CPI or WPI.
Table 4: If Deflation, then Prior Boom?
CPI deflation and share booms
Total periods of CPI deflation Industrial share price burst within 36 months prior No industrial share price burst
9 2 7
CPI deflation and property booms
Total periods of CPI deflation Residential property price burst within 36 months prior No residential property price burst
9 0 9
WPI deflation and share booms
Total periods of WPI deflation Industrial share price burst within 36 months prior No industrial share price burst
73 17 56
WPI deflation and property booms
Total periods of WPI deflation Residential property price burst within 36 months prior No residential property price burst
73 9 64
Note: Deflation is defined as two quarters or more (or 3/4, 5/6, etc) of negative change in CPI or WPI.

How tight was the connection between Japan's own asset-price bubble bursting and the performance of the Japanese economy? The first point to notice is that Japanese core CPI inflation continued to rise for five quarters after the stock market peak (Figure 8), and did not drop sharply until mid 1992; for comparison, the US inflation rate remained quite steady for the first two-and-a-half years after the peak and then declined slightly. There must have been a lagged effect from asset prices in Japan. Looking at real GDP growth (Figure 9) also depicts a Japanese economy with quite a bit of momentum: real growth was very strong in 1990 and above 3 per cent even in 1991. Though below 1 per cent for 1992–1994, growth remained positive throughout and came back strongly in 1995–1996 (growth in the US zeroed out in the first year after the bubble burst, and the strength of the current recovery remains to be seen). In both post-bubble economies, this looks like a normal mild recession that follows any monetary tightening. For Japan the underlying data bear this out. As Figure 10 shows, Japanese real consumption growth actually exceeded that of the legendarily retail-minded US in the first two years past the peak – both household and business confidence (Tankan survey measure) bottomed in 1993:Q4, and stock prices grew faster than earnings in 1993 and 1994. Expectations were for a full return to growth, unimpeded by concerns over asset-price declines or balance sheets. Business investment turned positive in FY1995, and private investment grew by 5.1 per cent in 1996.

Figure 8: Inflation Rates
Figure 9: Real GDP Growth
Figure 10: Real Consumption Growth

So 1990–1994 should be seen as a normal growth recession following monetary tightening. It was perhaps a bit unusual by the standards of Japan before the oil shock, but not all that much different than the 1985–1986 Endaka recession which, while shorter, actually saw the Japanese economy contract. And, as I argued in Posen (1998), it took extensive policy mistakes – insufficient monetary easing; contractionary fiscal policy; and forebearance of bank capital erosion and resultant misbehaviour – to kill off the 1995–1996 Japanese recovery. These mistakes, only the last of which has any direct relation to asset-price declines, are sufficient to account for the underperformance of Japan's economy and the onset of deflation from 1997 onwards. Even with regard to the erosion of bank capital, there were numerous regulatory and structural factors at work beyond the decline in stock and real estate prices.

The BOJ did cut its overnight interest rate nine times between July 1991 (from 6.0 per cent to 5.5 per cent) and September 1995 (reaching 0.5 per cent), and argued at the time and thereafter that this should have been ample ease (Ueda 2000; Okina and Shiratsuka 2003). The Federal Reserve Board's unofficial definitive study of the period (Ahearne et al 2002) agrees that, given the data and forecasts available in real-time, the BOJ did cut as much as could have been expected – they argue that it was just that deflationary pressures from asset-price declines were not taken into account sufficiently.[27] Had the BOJ cut an additional 200 basis points before end of 1994, it would have been enough to keep Japan on a growth path. Yet, even taking the limitations of contemporary data into account, Ahearne et al (2002) are too easy on the BOJ, and as a result give too much weight to the effect of asset-price declines. The aforementioned shift of the BOJ to counter-inflationary conservatism, and the concomitant underweighting of the output gap in decision-making, is embodied in the Taylor rule projection that Ahearne et al (2002) use to make their case that the BOJ responses were in line with data. It is true, as Kasa and Popper (1997) establish, that market participants anticipated the severe tightening of 1989–1991 and the slow loosening thereafter. This just emphasises that the course of monetary policy reflected a consistent set of BOJ preferences, not that it was necessarily a reasonable policy response.

Kuttner and Posen (2003) find that what applied in the end of the bubble period also applies in the bubble's aftermath: had the BOJ put a more reasonable weight on intermediate term output versus inflation goals, and therefore paid more attention to the information contained in the output gap, inputting any reasonable forward-looking measure of the output gap would have suggested more rapid interest rate cuts. This result relies solely on data available to the BOJ in real-time, and does not include any information from asset-price movements beyond those embodied in the output gap. The difference with the Ahearne et al (2002) result is in the weights. In a related exercise, Harrigan and Kuttner (2003) explicitly compare how the BOJ would have behaved if it had used the available data in a Taylor rule with ‘normal’ Fed weights versus one with ‘normal’ BOJ weights as in Ahearne et al (2002) (Figures 11 and 12). As shown in Figure 11, the Fed response would have been much more aggressive (again without including any asset price or asymmetric deflation risks explicitly). In fact, the normal Fed response alone would have yielded the earlier 200 bps in cuts that Ahearne et al (2002) estimate (using the FRB Global Model) would have been enough to offset deflationary pressures and the post-1996 recession.[28]

Figure 11: The BOJ's Response to Recession
Figure 12: The Fed's Response to US Recession

The cutting-off of the mid 1990s Japanese recovery was in fact overdetermined, because fiscal policy was sufficiently contractionary to have ended it on its own, absent any the monetary policy mistakes, and vice versa (Posen 1998). That is part of why the following recession has been so deep. From 1992–1995, Japanese fiscal policy was mostly stimulative, particularly in 1995, although by comparison with the US after its bubble, fiscal policy was slow to expand (Figure 13). Posen (2003c) shows in a cross-national investigation that Japan was the only OECD economy whose deficit response to business cycle declined over the 1990s, after starting out in the mid-range of responsiveness. While the infamous examples of pork barrel projects and bridges to nowhere certainly represented the nature of much of Japanese public works spending, these were not the main source of fiscal expansion. Rather, increasing social security payments for an aging society and tax cuts provided most of the bang during this period (as can be seen in Figure 14, Japanese government transfers followed a smooth trend, rather than going up as an automatic stabiliser, as they did in the US).

Figure 13: General Government Balances as a Per Cent of GDP
Figure 14: Government Consumption and Transfers

The yield curve was upward-sloping until 1996, consistent with a view that not only was fiscal austerity unexpected, but that recovery and inflation were expected – despite asset-price declines. In April 1997 at the start of the fiscal year, however, multiple tax increases – the implementation of a suspended increase in the consumption tax from 3 to 5 per cent; a rise in the income tax; the addition of co-payments to the national health insurance program – hit the economy, and this took out 2.5 per cent of GDP within three years (Kuttner and Posen 2002). From that point onwards, fiscal policy tended to be contractionary, and public investment has been declining since 1998. The recession of 1992–1994, the offsetting monetary tightness, and the occasional appreciations of the yen against the dollar had little impact on the revenue-minded Japanese fiscal policy-makers, and tax receipts went up significantly during the first three years after the bubble (see Figure 15). Since the yield curve has flattened and nominal long-term interest rates have declined while the public debt has mounted, there is no reason to think that significant Ricardian offsets for fiscal expansion would have arisen had fiscal policy been tried; econometric assessments of the effectiveness of Japanese fiscal policy support this view (Kuttner and Posen 2001a). Ahearne et al (2002) and Posen (1998) concur that had the tax hikes of 1997 been put off, the recovery of 1995–1996 would have continued to gain steam. Of course, a package combining fiscal and monetary stimulus would have been best.

Figure 15: Government Revenue

The third major policy mistake was forebearance of bank misbehaviour and capital erosion. This was the natural if unfortunate outcome of the structural shifts in the banking system following partial deregulation discussed above. As in the US Savings and Loan Crisis and other instances of financial fragility around the world, Japanese bank supervisors held off closing banks in hopes that the economy's return to growth and/or a rise in asset prices would restore bank profitability. In Japan, however, this phenomenon was taken to an extreme in duration and breadth, in part because the supervisors retained the Convoy notion that banks should not be allowed to exit the market. Figure 16 juxtaposes commercial banks' return on assets (ROA) with an index of the number of banks for Japan and the US.[29] In Japan, the number of banks five years after the stock market peak was 97 per cent of the number at the peak, and ROA had declined to nearly zero from the already low 0.3 ratio attained during the bubble; in the US, the number of banks was steadily declining through the boom years, and the trend continued into the post-bubble period, keeping bank profitability steady (ROA six-fold or more that of Japan).

Figure 16: Commercial Banks' Return on Assets and Number of Commercial Banks

During this post-bubble period in Japan (1990–present), banks have been allowed to evergreen loans to distressed borrowers, ration out new borrowers, and exploit those lending relationships which remain viable (Hoshi and Kashyap (2000); Peek and Rosengren (1997)). Japanese households went back to keeping nearly 60 per cent of their savings in bank deposits (including a quarter of that amount in Postal Savings), because the convoy system and deposit insurance gave them no incentive to move their money out (see Figure 17 for Japan and Figure 18 for the US) – and that kept the banks from having to compete for loanable funds. Adherence to the Basel I Capital Accord meant that Japanese banks had to maintain sufficient Tier II capital to reach 8 per cent by end of FY1992, but the Japanese government had negotiated hard to count latent share gains on banks' non-financial holdings as part of that Tier II capital (Ito and Sasaki 2002). As a result, it took until 1997 for equity prices to decline sufficiently to have an impact on the lending behaviour of Japanese banks.

Figure 17: Composition of Household Savings in Japan
Figure 18: Composition of Household Savings in the US

Had there been sufficient transparency in the Japanese banking system, with sufficient accountability to shareholders and supervisors, though, there either could have been enough Tier I capital issuance or banking sector consolidation – or even sales of long-held industrial shares – in the intervening seven years to offset the declines in Tier II capital due to cross-shareholdings. In fall 1997, however, abetted by the downturn of the economy and the fiscal tightening, financial failures shocked the Japanese public. Within a year, Hokkaido Takushoku Bank, Sanyo Securities, Yamaichi Securities, Long-Term Credit Bank, Nippon Credit Bank, and a number of minor firms failed despite government efforts to prop them up.[30] At this point the effects of a bank credit crunch did add to the contraction of the Japanese economy.[31]

So did the asset-price bubble cause Japan's Great Recession? Even the oft-used analogy of the balance sheet effects being the match which lit the fuse seems to exaggerate the bubble's direct impact. The 1991–1994 recession was well within normal bounds of a usual recession post-monetary tightening, nothing too arduous. Japanese monetary and fiscal policy austerity is sufficient to account for the abortion of the 1995–1996 recovery, a recovery that on all forward-looking indicators (including rising stock prices) looked to be sustainable. Neglect of basic financial supervision allowed balance sheet problems for banks to finally accumulate to where they impeded lending, after macroeconomic policy had already put the economy back into recession. If these extensive policy mistakes had not killed the 1995–1996 recovery off, and if the Japanese bank supervisors had taken only 10 years after partial deregulation to engage with the structural under-capitalisation of their banking sector, we would not be discussing the Japanese economy the way we do today (Posen 1998). With that proper perspective on the course of Japan's economy after the bubble in mind, we might not now be so concerned with the impact of bubbles on major economies in general, without the Japanese example to cite.

3. Did the Bubble Impede Restructuring?

No matter what the demand shock to an economy, it is never without sectoral impact. An economy undergoing adjustment has to reallocate workers and capital from less to more rewarding uses. With well-functioning markets, distressed assets are fairly and quickly repriced and re-employed. The question here is whether a bubble bursting is in and of itself sufficient to impede this process of restructuring. Given the recognition that some bubbles have significant macroeconomic costs and some do not, it is possible that the difference in costliness between bubbles accords with how well the economy reallocates capital afterwards. Obviously, financial systems that are dysfunctional impede this process of reallocation. Pomerleano (2003) establishes with cross-national data that specialised human capital, such as workout specialists and property appraisers, also is needed. In the end, many of the factors usually cited as good for economic growth are good for restructuring, which makes sense because the ongoing process of restructuring can be seen as the Schumpeterian engine of growth. As with the previous two sections, my argument is that we should shift attention away from the bubble as a causal force in its own right, and stress the response of Japanese authorities, businesses, and households.

The previous two sections addressed essentially retrospective questions: did monetary ease cause the Japanese bubble?; did the bubble cause Japan's recession? The restructuring issue requires something more of a counter-factual approach – tracing out the bubble's impact on restructuring needs a benchmark against which to measure progress. Therefore, insofar as data allow, we will compare the response of the US economy (known for its arms-length markets and corporate governance) to a given asset-price bubble, with the response of the Japanese economy (known for its web of corporate and financial relationships) to an almost identical asset-price bubble. Even where data limitations preclude us from making the comparison directly, it will be evident that the Japanese corporate sector responded to the bubble's burst by resisting restructuring for a multi-year period.[32]

The simplest point to be made is clear in Figure 19 showing the path of investment and national income in the two countries relative to peak in equity prices. In the US, income flattened out almost immediately upon the bubble's bursting, and investment declined – in Japan, however, investment continued to climb for two years after the bubble and so (at a slower rate) did income. The Japanese investor simply did not respond to the market signal. This could be because of the relationship banking system that encourages banks to carry clients through harder times while the securitised US system results in rapid financial cutbacks; this also could be because of evergreening and poor bank supervision in Japan. Figure 20 plots the quality spread between benchmark 10-year AA-class industrial bonds and Japanese government bonds, which began to rise in the year after the bubble's burst, but stayed well below pre-bubble levels (and at a relatively low differential compared to US spreads) – the bond market was insufficiently responsive.

Figure 19: Investment and Income
Figure 20: Japan – Quality Spread

A more important fact is shown in Figure 21 which presents the bank loans outstanding to the sectors in the Japanese economy which were at the heart of the bubble: finance, insurance and real estate (FIRE); services (in Japan, dominated by inefficient SMEs); and construction. Each one of these sectors saw loans outstanding to it continue to rise rather than shrink following the bubble years. In the case of construction, the trend in loan growth to the sector actually rose after the bubble.[33] The US does not break down lending data in flow of funds by sector, probably because of the lesser importance of banks in corporate finance. As Friedman (2000) notes, lending to real estate continued to rise in the US after the Savings and Loan Crisis, so this is not entirely atypical. Nonetheless, the expansion of lending on this scale in all these sectors is clearly an indicator of lack of adjustment of which sectors were favoured by lenders. Figure 22 further reflects adverse selection in Japanese credit markets post-bubble: the rate of firms going under in Japan (exiting business) actually declined starting in 1991, and stayed below pre-bubble levels, while the rate of new firm entry dropped markedly.

Figure 21: Japan – Loans and Discounts Outstanding by Sector
Figure 22: Japan – Firm Entry and Exit Rate

Overall, Japanese labour markets have engaged in a form of adverse selection analogous to that in bank lending. As is often anecdotally observed, Japanese firms that have stayed open have generally sought to maintain employment rather than restore profitability during the 1990s, even though this came at a cost of offering few opportunities to younger workers and school leavers. Figure 23 documents that the job separation rate rose only slightly in the immediate aftermath of the bubble before declining, while over time the decline in job entry rate accelerated. Lacking US job entry/exit data for the period, we can show how employment in various industries responded as an indicator of restructuring. In Figure 24 it can be seen that the same three sectors – construction, FIRE, and services – in Japan that have continued to get funding from their banks have increased their employment;[34] in the US, the information and communications technology (ICT) sector that was the darling of the American bubble saw employment contract immediately.

Figure 23: Japan – Job Entry and Separation Rate
Figure 24: Sectoral Employment Data

In keeping with the relative extent of re-allocation, labour productivity declined in Japan steadily over the years after the Nikkei peak (even discounting the artificial high of the 1988 productivity number), while US productivity has continued to grow in the three years since the S&P 500 peak, and the latest numbers released promise a continuation of the trend (Figure 25). As a result, real corporate profits computed from the national accounts (Figure 26), not accounting profits, have rebounded from a short post-bubble decline in the US, and were generally a steady number; in Japan, corporate profits traced the boom upwards, and declined for five straight years after the peak.

Figure 25: Labour Productivity Growth
Figure 26: Corporate Profitability

Two analogous bubbles produced very different degrees of restructuring, so it is not about the bubble.[35] Given that Japan does have the basic institutions, property rights, and to a large degree financial expertise necessary for a successful restructuring (or can easily import it from eager providers), why did restructuring not occur? A large measure of the blame must go to the management of the Japanese banks who not only have the usual undercapitalised lenders' incentives to misallocate credit, but who also have been accustomed to extracting rents from corporate clients, depositors, and even government officials, and therefore have every incentive to keep current relationships going.[36] Yet their lack of accountability to shareholders or public officials, and their ability to tie up so much of Japanese savings requires more to be successful. Posen (2003a, 2003b) argues that four factors create the Japan syndrome leading to sustained deflation: undercapitalised banks with incomplete deregulation; passive savers and voters; a lack of openness to international pressures (or exits by savers and firms); and contractionary macroeconomic policies. The question remains open, but the role of macroeconomic policy in restructuring merits further consideration.

4. Could Monetary Policy Have Encouraged Restructuring?

After an asset-price boom has ended, and the need for restructuring becomes apparent, the central bank has a choice to make. Inflation is unlikely to be a threat for an extended period, giving some room to focus on growth. The central bank therefore can either tighten monetary conditions in hopes of inducing faster or more complete restructuring, or it can loosen monetary conditions in hopes of easing the restructuring process. This is the old debate between liquidationists and expansionists, seen around the world during the early 1930s. Then US Treasury Secretary Andrew Mellon was seen as the exemplar of the liquidationist view urging policies to ‘get the rot out’; Keynes would be the embodiment, if not the creator, of the expansionist alternative. In Japan since the bubble burst, but particularly since the 1997 recession and the emergence of steady deflation, the debate has been revived, and both points of view have been heard. What are the economic and political assumptions underlying the respective positions?

The view that creative destruction requires liquidations has often been espoused by top BOJ officials. In summer 2000, in anticipation of the interest rate increase to be undertaken that August, BOJ Governor Masaru Hayami gave a series of press interviews and speeches advocating this view.[37] Fundamentally, low or zero interest rates are said to impede restructuring because they allow inefficient firms to make their loan payments and remain open. Those sharing this view, such as the Japanese business pundit Tadashi Nakamae (2000, 2003), advocate raising interest rates to increase bankruptcies and raise efficiency in the economy. Efforts by monetary policy-makers to ease the pain of adjustment will likely decrease the incentive of businesses, interest groups, and government to undertake necessary restructuring (shades of the European Central Bank can be seen here). In fact, low or zero interest rates have the political effect of inviting wasteful government spending in place of reform. In all, the idea is to impose greater market discipline by making credit markets tighter.

The opposing view holds that restructuring goes best in a supportive environment, and that efforts to increase destruction of firms and jobs are often uncreative. Most of today's mainstream macroeconomic models that include imperfect information and financial intermediation support this view, and the existence of nominal rigidities adds to the argument for expansionist policies.[38] Low or negative real interest rates aid restructuring because they improve the investment incentives of borrowers. As Bernanke and Gertler (1990) argue, the appropriate response to financial fragility is to restore the net worth of borrowers so they have something at stake in their economic activity and pursue the proper projects. Obviously, inflation and liquidity are one means by which to do this. Sorting out firms for life or bankruptcy based upon which ones happen to hit a liquidity constraint when interest rates rise is a very poor screen for investment or management quality, making monetary policy too blunt an instrument (Mussa 2003; Posen 2000a). Politically, the assumption is that governments will pander to interest groups almost inevitably, but governments with additional resources are better able to buy off entrenched interest groups into lasting change. A more buoyant economic environment may also reduce the incentive for interest groups to dig in their protections.

Looking at the one case of Japan will not settle this debate, but it does give us strong indications of where the truth lies. In fact, given that many thought the debate settled against the liquidationists by the Great Depression, only to have the old arguments resurface in the fact of Japan's Great Recession, there may be no hope of settling it. Yet, the comparison of US and Japanese experiences post-bubble does provide a useful if not compelling heuristic – and it is one in favour of the expansionist view. Short-term real interest rates declined much further much faster in the US than in Japan in the aftermath of the bubble (Figure 27), with a differential of nearly 300 basis points three years out. Leaving aside the concerns from Sections 1 and 2 about whether the decline was commensurate with the surrounding economic conditions, what effect did this have on the restructuring?

Figure 27: Real Interest Rates

Section 3 has already given us our answer: the US economy changed lending and employment patterns more in those three post-equity peak years than the Japanese economy has in the 13 years since its stock market peak. This may not have been the only determinant, but loosening monetary policy did not impede restructuring. In fact, as shown in Figure 28, the yield curve on government bonds (10-year minus 3-month) steepened far more in the US than in Japan over the same immediate post-bubble period, even though the Japanese yield curve did steepen some. And the economy which had the steeper yield curve had sounder bank behaviour, as one would expect via the profitability channel. Finally, the ongoing willingness of Japanese households to keep just below 60 per cent of their savings in bank deposits (in comparison to the US share of below 20 per cent – see Figure 29) reflects in part the high risk-free real interest rates and distortions of investment, but in turn feeds those structural problems.

Figure 28: Term-yield Spreads
Figure 29: Household Deposits

5. What Central Bankers Should Learn from Japan's Bubble

So did the asset-price bubble cause Japan's Great Recession? Even the oft-used analogy of the bubble's balance-sheet effects being the match which lit the fuse seems to exaggerate the Japanese bubble's direct impact. The 1991–1994 recession was well within normal bounds of a usual recession post-monetary tightening, nothing too destructive or persistent. Japanese monetary and fiscal policy austerity is sufficient, without any reference to balance-sheet effects, to account for the abortion of the 1995–96 recovery, a recovery that on all forward-looking indicators (including rising stock prices) looked to be sustainable. Neglect of basic financial supervision allowed balance-sheet problems for banks to finally accumulate to where they impeded lending starting in 1997, after macroeconomic policy had already put the economy back into recession. If these extensive policy mistakes had not killed the 1995–1996 recovery off, and if the Japanese bank supervisors had taken only 10 years after partial deregulation to engage with the structural undercapitalisation of their banking sector, we would not be discussing the Japanese economy the way we do today (Posen 1998).

With an accurate understanding of the sources of Japan's economic underperformance after the bubble – one that, as argued here, does not include the bubble itself as a direct cause of that underperformance – monetary policy-makers and pundits might not be giving as much attention to the debate over whether policy should respond to bubbles as they currently do. Monetary policy clearly was (and remains) a contributing factor to Japan's stagnation, but it was not disregard of asset prices either on their way up or of their effects on the way down which led to the monetary policy decisions made by the BOJ. The BOJ should have been able to tighten policy more quickly in the late 1980s and loosen policy more quickly in the early 1990s without any particular reference to asset-price movements – and in any event, monetary policy might well have been unable to stop those movements. Negative developments in the Japanese economy after the bubble were hardly driven by the fall in asset values, but rather by other problems in the Japanese economy (including overly tight monetary policy itself). Comparative analysis broadly of other recent cases of asset-price booms and, in more depth, of developments in the US in parallel (relative to its asset-price peak) with developments in Japan, support my conclusion that a primary concern for monetary policy should be how to encourage restructuring in the aftermath of a boom, not the boom itself.

Thus, I take away four lessons for central bankers about asset prices and monetary policy from Japan's bubble and response to it.

First, bubbles will come, bubbles will go, but monetary policy remains the same. The highly charged discussions in the last few years whether or not central banks should include asset prices in their decision-making seem unnecessary. If central bankers worry sufficiently about assessing potential output – using real-time data but also benchmarking appropriately with international comparisons and historical trends – and check credit aggregates for consistency with their assessment, they do not need to get into the game of evaluating equity prices. This perhaps seems to be a sleight of hand, where assessing potential output is really no easier than looking at appropriate P/E ratios, but that is mistaken. Given the huge difference in volatility between potential and equity prices, as well as the statistical techniques available for estimating potential without much in the way of assumptions, and the relatively sensible benchmarks for what potential can be, this is a much more tractable task. And in any event, central banks have to estimate potential output no matter what.

Thus, it is surges in lending rather than in real estate or stock prices per se that should attract the attention of the central bank. Issing (2002) makes a case that this is a good reason for central banks to track broad money supply growth measures as well as inflation, as the European Central Bank does. While that may be a bit too pat, it certainly reminds us that the point of the exercise is not simple policy rules, with a yes/no on targeting asset prices, but rather to pursue an information-inclusive strategy. It is in this sense that central banks should worry more about communicating with markets and the broader public about the contingent nature of their assessments than sticking with a foolish consistency. In all these regards, inflation targeting (in the flexible manner practiced by all major central banks with inflation targets) will help, even though it will not solve everything. Flexible inflation targeting will prevent undue emphasis on inflation goals without reference to output gaps; flexible inflation targeting will be information inclusive rather than strictly rule based; and flexible inflation targeting will provide a framework for communicating with the public.

Second, it is what happens after the bubble bursts that is truly important for macroeconomic outcomes. Since bubbles do not always result in deflation or even in unusually deep recessions, there should be more emphasis on financial stability and reactive policy (as many in Hunter et al (2003) also argued). As I stated in Tokyo in January 2001: ‘The [US] stock market probably was a bubble, at least in tech stocks, that has burst. What the much softer landing in the US than it was in Japan demonstrates is how financial regulation and supervision and monetary policy, rather than the stock market itself, determine the impact of a bubble’ (Posen 2001a). Meanwhile, the impact of monetary policy movements on the generation and inflation of bubbles is unclear, even if one took them into account for pre-emptive purposes, whereas we know monetary policy can affect the output gap and distressed financial systems beneficially in the short-run. Central banks should also not hide behind bubbles, claiming they cannot do anything after a bubble has burst or that the bubble confused them – they have to take responsibility for their part in the aftermath.

Third, fewer banks, fewer crises.[39] I mean this in three senses. One, if an economy has a smaller share of corporate financing running through banks, and there are more developed alternative forms of financing, adjustment will be smoother and the impact of collateral declines will be smaller. Two, if an economy keeps a smaller share of household savings in bank accounts, there will be stronger checks upon the banking system from households both economically (as savers) and politically (as voters) than when they passively accept what the banks do to them. Three, fewer banks within a given nation's banking sector, that is higher concentration, improves profitability and therefore capital and behaviour. Bank dependent systems will do worse with the aftermath of bubbles.

Fourth and finally, monetary ease is the appropriate reaction to the burst of bubbles. Japan has proven the liquidationists wrong again. When an economy has a serious deficit of demand, a broken financial system, and/or approaches the zero interest rate bound, fiscal and monetary policy should work in tandem. Relying on two tools rather than one exclusively will increase credibility as well as decrease distortions for a given combined stimulative effect. Claims that such post-burst expansions induce moral hazard among the investors writ large (e.g. Miller et al (2002)) would be the one plausible argument against such ease. These claims, however, do not appear to be borne out empirically. Looking at the list of asset-price booms from Bordo and Jeanne (2002) (see Table A1) finds few if any repeat offenders in booms. This moral hazard concern relies too much on a macroeconomist's representative agent view, and ignores both the fears of the individual investor and the real moral hazards of the financial intermediaries. Those micro-level people's micro-level incentives regarding willingness to invest swamp any effect from an expansionary monetary policy.

Appendix

Table A1: List of OECD Booms
Country Boom in residential property prices
1970–1998
Boom in industrial share prices
1970–2001
Australia 1987–1990 1985–1987
Canada 1986–1989  
Denmark 1983–1986 1981–1984
Finland 1986–1989 and 1996–1998 1982–1984; 1986–1988;
1993–1995 and 1997–2001
France   1984–1986 and 1996–2000
Germany   1983–1986 and 1996–2000
Ireland 1977–1979 and 1996–1998 1985–1988 and 1996–1998
Italy 1973–1976; 1979–1981 and 1988–1991 1979–1981; 1984–1987 and 1996–2000
Japan 1973 and 1985–1990 1984–1989
Netherlands 1974–1977 1983–1985 and 1995–2000
Norway 1973–1974 and 1984–1987 1983–1985
Spain 1985–1991 1984–1988 and 1996–2001
Sweden 1987–1989 1981–1984 and 1996–2000
UK 1973 and 1986–1989  
US   1996–2000

Source: Bordo and Jeanne (2002), pp 147–148

Footnotes

Contact: aposen@iie.com. Prepared for the Reserve Bank of Australia 2003 Conference on Asset Prices and Monetary Policy. I am extremely grateful to Samantha Davis for outstanding research assistance, and to Nobuyuki Asai, Kenneth Kuttner, Mikihiro Matsuoka, Tomoyuki Ohta, Stefano Scarpetta, Charles Steindel, Tadao Yanase, Kazuhiko Yano, and especially Arthur Alexander, Tetsuro Sugiura, and Cameron Umetsu, for timely and thoughtful advice. Gordon de Brouwer, my discussant, and participants in the RBA 2003 Conference provided helpful comments. All opinions and errors in this document are solely my own. This research is part of my project on deflation for the Institute for International Economics. [1]

My take on the first set of questions, regarding monetary stimulus at the zero-bound in Japan and elsewhere, is given in Posen (2000b), Posen (2003c), and Kuttner and Posen (2001a). [2]

See, inter alia, Bordo and Jeanne (2002), Borio and Lowe (2001), and IMF (2000). [3]

As I point out in Posen (2003a, 2003b), this is a particularly pointed question for Germany. A plot of the German DAX index would be much the same except even steeper, and Germany shares many though not all aspects of Japan's political economy. [4]

Examples of this literature include Bernanke (2000) and Greenspan (2002) against targeting asset prices, and Blanchard (2000) and Miller, Weller and Zhang (2002) in favour of central banks directly responding, with many essays in Hunter, Kaufman and Pomerleano (2003) taking one or the other side. [5]

In general, the academic finance literature dwells on whether bubbles actually can exist, whether any given bubble is rational, and so on. In contrast, the policy and descriptive literature on Japan in the late 1980s refers to the period as ‘The Bubble Economy’, and even academic treatments claiming the Japanese asset-price booms were bubbles are common. For the purposes of this paper, the Japanese asset-price boom will be referred to as a bubble, but other countries' experiences will be called asset-price booms without claiming to justify characterising them as bubbles. [6]

And, in this view, the MOF itself was easing due to pressure from the US government (see discussion below). [7]

This point is made in Kashyap (2000) and Goodfriend (2003), among other places. [8]

For example, as Hutchison (1994) points out using Japanese data, a drop in interest rates today might drive up housing prices in the short term by making them more affordable, but in the medium-term tends to drive prices down because it portends a monetary tightening or slower growth. Aggregate supply factors tend to dominate monetary factors as consistent determinants of land prices. [9]

The threshold is defined in their paper by 1.3 times the average standard deviation. They choose this threshold to identify the obvious booms without catching too many. See Bordo and Jeanne (2002). [10]

Details on the data sources and the country-specific monetary aggregates used, including adapting to the advent of the euro as appropriate, are given in Table A1. [11]

We include in our list of sustained periods those where one quarter shows tighter policy after the minimum two-in-a-row if that quarter is followed by a least one quarter back to ease, i.e., a run of 3-out-of-4 quarters or 4-out-of-5 quarters of M3 growth above threshold (r<1%) is deemed as one period of sustained ease. No results depend meaningfully on this assumption, but it seems practical. [12]

Excepting the last quarter, to allow for some lag between the start of interest rate increases/monetary tightening and the boom bursting. One could allow more time for tightening at the end of any boom, presumably because it takes a while for monetary tightening to have an effect on asset prices, but that would seem to contradict precisely the second version of the point being tested, that monetary ease is necessary for the bubble to continue. [13]

Jinushi et al (2000) give a good English-language summary from a Japanese perspective, while complementary recountings are given by Henning (2003) and Siebert (2000), from American and European perspectives respectively. Hoshi and Kashyap (2001, Ch 7) covers the period with an emphasis on financial market developments. [14]

Posen (2001b) explains why, using similar reasoning, one would interpret the 1990s as a period of rising potential growth in Japan, not least because of ample deregulation (notably in financial services, energy, retail, and telecommunications) and the IT revolution, as well as changes in female labour force participation. [15]

Ueda (2003) actually goes further, suggesting that the bubble's decline was inevitable because there was ‘a secular decline in the return on capital [in Japan] starting sometime in the late 1980s’. This is a view echoed by other Japanese officials who, like BOJ Policy Board member Kazuo Ueda, came to power in the mid 1990s and wished to explain, if not excuse, Japanese economic performance. Of course, this would suggest even more strongly that the bubble was irrational and beyond the control of the BOJ, and that the BOJ should have raised rates even earlier or more sharply in the 1980s than Bernanke and Gertler (2000) suggested it should have. Posen (2001b) and Kuttner and Posen (2001a) discuss the tendency for Japanese official estimates to understate the growth potential of Japan in hindsight. [16]

Empirically, the McKinnon-Ohno thesis does not hold up – that is, movements in the dollar-yen exchange rate do not one-way Granger-cause movements in the Japanese price level or expectations, even in simple two-variable regressions (see Posen (2003c)). The point here though is that even if the monetary ease were held to be sustainable due to the US pressure rather than false economic assumptions, that too would require false economic assumptions by the market participants. [17]

Friedman (2000), among others, points out that this followed the exact same logic as the US Savings and Loan Crisis, complete with accompanying real estate boom/busts. [18]

See Figure 21. Hoshi and Kashyap (2000) and Shimizu (2000) present various other measures of this boom in lending to small business. [19]

Tax incentives in the inheritance system and elsewhere also encouraged older individuals to borrow against land. See Ito and Iwaisako (1995). [20]

See Bernanke and Gertler (2000) versus Okina and Shiratsuka (2003). [21]

Of course, there are ways to take asset-price developments into account in monetary policy-making without going all the way to including it in a rule. Bordo and Jeanne (2002) and Mussa (2003) make the case for such discretionary inclusion, saying central banks need to recognise and respond to exceptional circumstances. [22]

See Truman (forthcoming), Posen (2000b) and Kuttner and Posen (2001b), and the references therein. [23]

Bernanke and Gertler (1999), Jinushi et al (2000), and Kuttner and Posen (2001a) all find in estimated BOJ reaction functions a similar shift in relative weights, a significant decline in the weight on output information, and date this break to around 1987. [24]

Yamaguchi (1999) states: ‘In fact, much of Japan's difficulties in the 1990s clearly has its origins in the asset market swing in the last 15 years … The damage left on the balance sheet of firms, both financial and non-financial, has been enormous’. See also Hayami (2000b). [25]

We focus on the date asset-price booms end (i.e., the peak value) rather than dating periods of actual ongoing busts (as Bordo and Jeanne (2002) do) because the point is precisely to find out whether asset-price declines cause busts. Thus, in Tables 3 and 4 we refer to ‘bursts’ as the time the prices begin falling. [26]

Then BOJ Deputy Governor Yukata Yamaguchi (2002) picks up that line of argument, that the contractionary effects of insufficient monetary ease were the result of unforseen drag from asset-price deflation, but cuts would have been sufficient for normal circumstances. [27]

Similarly, Harrigan and Kuttner (2003) find that the Fed has cut rates since the US bubble burst in line with its ‘normal’ response, given weights on output and inflation, and given real-time information – without reference to the extreme movements in asset prices (see Figure 12). [28]

There is a jump in the number of banks listed in 1988 (peak–1) for Japan due to a reclassification of certain institutions. The actual number of core commercial banks was flat and did not increase. [29]

Hoshi and Kashyap (2001, Ch 8) gives a good history of this period. [30]

Bayoumi (2001), Cargill et al (2000), Ito and Sasaki (2002), Ogawa (2003), Peek and Rosengren (1997, 2003), and Shimizu (2000) all offer evidence to this effect. [31]

For no doubt historical and institutional reasons, the US government collects less data on the micro-level about the activities of specific firms and workers than the Japanese government does. [32]

This is probably in part due to the use by Japanese governments of public works construction projects as employment programs, making the loans seem to be implicitly government backed. See Posen (1998, pp 29–54) and Kuttner and Posen (2001a) for discussions of the growth in construction employment. [33]

Ogawa (2003) using firm-level data shows a clear link between availability of credit and employment at Japanese SMEs. [34]

Rosengren (2003) suggests that post-bubble reaction may be more important for macroeconomic performance than pre-bubble pre-emption. [35]

Among those empirical studies documenting the successful though destructive rent-seeking behaviour of Japanese banks are McGuire (2002, 2003); Morck, Nakamura and Shivdasani (2000); Peek and Rosengren (2003); Petersen and Rajan (1995); Smith (2003); Van Rixtel and Hassink (2002); and Weinstein and Yafeh (1998). [36]

See, for example, Bremmer (2000a, 2000b, 2000c), Hayami (2000a), Spindle (2000a, 2000b), and Tett and Abrahams (1999), as well as the references in Posen (2003c). [37]

Posen (1998, pp 143–157) summarises the relevant literature, drawing on the work of Akerlof, Bernanke, Stiglitz, and others. [38]

In Posen (2002, 2003d) I made this case in detail, drawing lessons from Japan's experience for emerging markets. [39]

References

Ahearne A, J Gagnon, J Haltmaier and S Kamin, C Erceg, J Faust, Luca Guerrieri, C Hemphill, L Kole, J Ruosh, J Rogers, N Sheets and J Wright (2002), ‘Preventing deflation: lessons from Japan's experience in the 1990s’, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve International Finance Discussion Paper No 729.

Bayoumi T (2001), ‘The morning after: explaining the slowdown in Japanese growth in the 1990s’, Journal of International Economics, 53(2), pp 241–259.

Bernanke BS (1983), ‘Nonmonetary effects of the financial crisis in the propagation of the Great Depression’, American Economic Review, 73(3), pp 257–276.

Bernanke BS (2000), ‘Japanese monetary policy: a case of self-induced paralysis?’, in AS Posen and R Mikitani (eds), Japan's financial crisis and its parallels to U.S. experience, Special Report 13, Institute for International Economics, Washington DC, pp 149–166.

Bernanke BS and M Gertler (1990), ‘Financial fragility and economic performance’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(1), pp 87–114.

Bernanke BS and M Gertler (2000), ‘Monetary policy and asset price volatility’, in New challenges for monetary policy: a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Kansas City, pp 77–128.

Blanchard O (2000), ‘Bubbles, liquidity traps, and monetary policy’, in AS Posen and R Mikitani (eds), Japan's financial crisis and its parallels to U.S. experience, Special Report 13, Institute for International Economics, Washington DC, pp 185–193.

Bordo M and O Jeanne (2002), ‘Monetary policy and asset prices: does “benign neglect” make sense?’, International Finance, 5(2), pp 139–164.

Borio C, C Furfine and P Lowe (2001), ‘Procyclicality of the financial system and financial stability: issues and policy options’, in Marrying the macro- and micro-prudential dimensions of financial stability, BIS Papers No 1, Basel, pp 1–57.

Borio C and P Lowe (2002), ‘Asset prices, financial and monetary stability: exploring the nexus’, BIS Working Papers No 114.

Bremmer B (2000a), ‘Inside the Bank of Japan (int'l edition)’, BusinessWeek Online, International – Asian cover story, 12 June, available at <http://www.businessweek.com/2000/00_24/b3685012.htm>.

Bremmer B (2000b), ‘Interview with the taskmaster (int'l edition)’, BusinessWeek Online, 12 June, available at <http://www.businessweek.com/2000/00_24/b3685012.htm>.

Bremmer B (2000c), ‘No…to a stop-and-go policy: a talk with Japan's Yutaka Yamaguchi’, BusinessWeek Online, 12 June, available at <http://www.businessweek.com/2000/00_24/b3685012.htm>.

Cargill T, M Hutchison, and T Ito (2000), Financial policy and central banking in Japan, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.

de Brouwer (1998), ‘Estimating output gaps’, Reserve Bank of Australia Research Discussion Paper No 9809.

Friedman B (2000), ‘Japan now and the United States then: lessons from the parallels’, in AS Posen and R Mikitani (eds), Japan's financial crisis and its parallels to U.S. experience, Special Report 13, Institute for International Economics, Washington DC, pp 37–56.

Goodfriend M (2003), ‘Interest rate policy should not react directly to asset prices’, in WC Hunter, GG Kaufman and M Pomerleano (eds), Asset price bubbles: the implications for monetary, regulatory, and international policies, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass, pp 445–457.

Greenspan A (2002), ‘Economic volatility’, remarks at a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson Hole, 28–30 August.

Harrigan J and K Kuttner (2003), ‘Is the U.S. going the way of Japan?’, Solutions for the Japanese Economy Project, Columbia University and Federal Reserve Bank of New York, mimeo.

Hayami M (2000a), ‘Opening speech’, address delivered at the 9th International Conference held by the Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies on ‘The role of monetary policy under low inflation’, Tokyo, 3 July.

Hayami M (2000b), ‘The US and Japanese economies: reflections of a central banker’, address delivered at the 32nd Annual Joint Meeting of Japan-Midwest U.S. Association, Tokyo, 11 September.

Hayashi F and E Prescott (2000), ‘The 1990s in Japan: a lost decade’, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Working Paper 607.

Henning CR (2003), ‘Japan's resistance to macroeconomic gaiatsu’, Institute for International Economics, mimeo.

Hoshi T and A Kashyap (2000), ‘The Japanese banking crisis: where did it come from and how will it end’, in BS Bernanke and J Rotemberg (eds), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1999, 14, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass, pp 129–201.

Hoshi T and A Kashyap (2001), Corporate financing and governance in Japan: the road to the future, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.

Hunter WC, GG Kaufman and M Pomerleano (eds) (2003), Asset price bubbles: the implications for monetary, regulatory, and international policies, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.

Hutchison M (1994), ‘Asset price fluctuation in Japan: what role for monetary policy?’, Bank of Japan Monetary and Economic Studies, 12(2), pp 61–83.

IMF (International Monetary Fund) (2000), ‘Chapter III: Asset prices and the business cycle’, World economic outlook: asset prices and the business cycle, May, pp 77–112.

Issing O (2002), ‘Why stable prices and stable markets are important and how they fit together’, European Central Bank, mimeo.

Ito T and T Iwaisako (1995), ‘Explaining asset bubbles in Japan’, NBER Working Paper No 5358.

Ito T and YN Sasaki (2002), ‘Impacts of the Basel capital standard on Japanese banks' behavior’, Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 16(3), pp 372–397.

Jinushi T, Y Kuroki and R Miyao (2000), ‘Monetary policy in Japan since the late 1980s: delayed policy actions and some explanations’, in AS Posen and R Mikitani (eds), Japan's financial crisis and its parallels to U.S. experience, Special Report 13, Institute for International Economics, Washington DC, pp 115–148.

Kasa K and H Popper (1997), ‘Monetary policy in Japan: a structural VAR analysis’, Journal of Japanese and International Economics, 11(3), pp 275–295.

Kashyap A (2000), ‘Discussion of the financial crisis’, in AS Posen and R Mikitani (eds), Japan's financial crisis and its parallels to U.S. experience, Special Report 13, Institute for International Economics, Washington DC, pp 106–114.

Kiyotaki N and J Moore (1997), ‘Credit cycles’, Journal of Political Economy, 105(2), pp 211–248.

Koo RC (2003), Balance sheet recession: Japan's struggle with uncharted economics and its global implications, John Wiley & Sons (Asia), Singapore.

Kuttner KN (1994), ‘Estimating potential ouput as a latent variable’, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 12(3), pp 361–368.

Kuttner KN and AS Posen (2001a), ‘The great recession: lessons for macroeconomic policy from Japan’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, pp 93–185.

Kuttner KN and AS Posen (2001b), ‘Inflation, monetary transparency, and G3 exchange rate volatility’, in M Balling, E Hochreiter and E Hennessy (eds), Adapting to financial globalization, International Studies in Money and Banking Vol 14, Routledge, London, pp 229–258.

Kuttner KN and AS Posen (2002), ‘Fiscal policy effectiveness in Japan’, Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 16(4), pp 536–558.

Kuttner KN and AS Posen (2003), ‘The difficulty of discerning what's too tight: Taylor rules and Japanese monetary policy’, Institute for International Economics, mimeo.

McGuire P (2002), ‘Japanese firm performance and bank affiliation: evidence of rent extraction’, BIS, mimeo.

McGuire P (2003), ‘Bank ties and bond market access: evidence on investment-cash flow sensitivity in Japan’, NBER Working Paper No 9644.

Miller M, P Weller and L Zhang (2002), ‘Moral hazard and the US stock market: analysing the “Greenspan put”’, Economic Journal, 112(478), pp C171–C186.

Mishkin FS and EN White (2002), ‘U.S. stock market crashes and their aftermath: implications for monetary policy’, NBER Working Paper No 8992.

Morck R, M Nakamura and A Shivdasani (2000), ‘Banks, ownership structure, and firm value in Japan’, Journal of Business, 73(4), pp 539–567.

Mussa M (2003), ‘Asset prices and monetary policy’, in WC Hunter, GG Kaufman and M Pomerleano (eds), Asset price bubbles: the implications for monetary, regulatory, and international policies, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass, pp 41–50.

Nakamae T (2000), ‘Why reform?’, Nihon Keizai Shimbun, 4 January.

Nakamae T (2001), ‘As the Japanese economy withers once again, the world wonders whether the U.S. will have its own “Japan problems”’, NIER Quarterly Report, March.

Nakamae T (2003), ‘Fukui's mission impossible’, The International Economy, 42(3), pp 87–90.

Ogawa K (2003), ‘Financial distress and employment: the Japanese case in the 90s’, NBER Working Paper No 9646.

Okina, K and S Shiratsuka (2003), ‘Japan's experience with asset price bubbles: is it a case for inflation targeting?’, in WC Hunter, GG Kaufman and M Pomerleano (eds), Asset price bubbles: the implications for monetary, regulatory, and international policies, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass, pp 81–99.

Peek J and E Rosengren (1997), ‘The international transmission of financial shocks: the case of Japan’, American Economic Review, 87(4), pp 495–505.

Peek J and E Rosengren (2003), ‘Unnatural selection: perverse incentives and the misallocation of credit in Japan’, NBER Working Paper No 9643.

Petersen M and R Rajan (1995), ‘The effect of credit market competition on lending relationships’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(2), pp 407–443.

Pomerleano M (2003), ‘The morning after: restructing in the aftermath of an asset bubble’, in WC Hunter, GG Kaufman and M Pomerleano (eds), Asset price bubbles: the implications for monetary, regulatory, and international policies, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass, pp 503–516.

Posen AS (1998), Restoring Japan's economic growth, Institute for International Economics, Washington DC.

Posen AS (2000a), ‘Little creative benefit in recession’, Financial Times, 2 August, p 11.

Posen AS (2000b), ‘The political economy of deflationary monetary policy’, in AS Posen and R Mikitani (eds), Japan's financial crisis and its parallels to U.S. experience, Special Report 13, Institute for International Economics, Washington DC, pp 194–208.

Posen AS (2001a), ‘Beware of policy overreactions: managing changing macroeconomic conditions in Japan and the United States’, delivered at Keidanren Think Tankers' Reunion Symposium, Tokyo, 17 January.

Posen AS (2001b), ‘Recognizing Japan's rising potential growth’, NIRA Review, 8(1), pp 48–53.

Posen AS (2002), ‘Fewer banks, fewer crises’, Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey Lecture given at the ‘International Conference in Economics VI’, held by Middle East Technical University, Ankara, 11 September.

Posen AS (2003a), ‘Frog in the pot: Germany's path to the Japan syndrome’, The National Interest, 71, pp 105–117.

Posen AS (2003b), ‘Is Germany turning Japanese?’, Institute for International Economics Working paper No 03-2.

Posen AS (2003c), ‘Japanese macroeconomic policy: unusual?’, Institute for International Economics, mimeo.

Posen AS (2003d), ‘A strategy to prevent future crises: safely shrink the banking sector’, in E Demaestri and P Masci (eds), Financial crises in Japan and Latin America, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington DC, pp 259–272.

Posen AS and Mikitani R (eds) (2000), Japan's financial crisis and its parallels to U.S. experience, Special Report 13, Institute for International Economics, Washington DC.

Rosengren E (2003), ‘Comments on “the morning after”’, in WC Hunter, GG Kaufman and M Pomerleano (eds), Asset price bubbles: the implications for monetary, regulatory, and international policies, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass, pp 529–533.

Shimizu Y (2000), ‘Convoy regulation, bank management, and the financial crisis in Japan’, in AS Posen and R Mikitani (eds), Japan's financial crisis and its parallels to U.S. experience, Special Report 13, Institute for International Economics, Washington DC, pp 57–99.

Shiratsuka S (1999), ‘Asset price fluctuation and price indices’, IMES Discussion Paper Series No 99-E-21.

Siebert H (2000), ‘The Japanese bubble: some lessons for international macroeconomic policy coordination’, Aussenwirtschaft, 55(2), pp 233–250.

Smith DC (2003), ‘Loans to Japanese borrowers’, Federal Reserve System International Finance Discussion Paper No 769.

Spindle B (2000a), ‘Hayami sees role as enforcer – BOJ chief makes case for rate rise to force firms to restructure’, Asian Wall Street Journal, 5 June, p 1.

Spindle B (2000b), ‘Heard in Asia: rate rise alone is unlikely to spoil Japan's recovery’, Asian Wall Street Journal, 14 August, p 13.

Tett G and P Abrahams (1999), ‘Japan's big issue’, Financial Times, 12 February, p 19.

Truman E (forthcoming), Inflation targeting in the world economy, Institute for International Economics, Washington DC.

Ueda K (2000), ‘Remarks’, delivered at a Conference held by the International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies and CEPR on ‘Asset price inflation: what to do about it?’, Geneva, 5 May.

Ueda K (2003), ‘Deflation and monetary policy in Japan’, Center on Japanese Economy and Business, Columbia University, mimeo.

Van Rixtel A and W Hassink (2002), ‘Monitoring the monitors: are old boys networks being used to monitor Japanese private banks?’, Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 16(1), pp 1–30.

Weinstein DE and Y Yafeh (1998), ‘On the costs of a bank-centered financial system: evidence from the changing main bank relations in Japan’, Journal of Finance, 53(2), pp 635–672.

Yamaguchi Y (1999), ‘Asset prices and monetary policy: Japan's experience’, in New challenges for monetary policy: a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Kansas City, pp 77–128.

Yamaguchi Y (2002), ‘Monetary policy in a changing economic environment’, remarks at a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson Hole, 28–30 August.