RDP 9303: The 1893 Bank Crashes and Monetary Aggregates 5. Liquidity of Long-Dated Bank Liabilities

It was argued above that the long-dated deposit receipts and deposit stock should be netted out from the money stock in view of the extension of the maturity of these liabilities. The series of M2 and M3 presented above in Table 4 represent the lower bound of monetary aggregates. While these 1893 bank deposits were ‘locked up’ as a different type of liability, they might still be considered as part of the stock of money. They possessed a degree of liquidity from late 1893 as a secondary market sprang up in these claims. Bank deposit receipts and stocks were traded on the Sydney Stock Exchange by September while these securities were placed on the official lists of the Sydney and Melbourne exchanges in December. The Official List of the Stock Exchange of Melbourne indicates that these stocks were traded on a daily basis in the first week of December[12]. A number of banks accepted deposit receipts at face value in settlement of their customers' outstanding debts. Private investors entered the market, particularly as rates offered by trading banks on their 24 month term deposits fell from 5 per cent in August 1893 to 3 per cent by October 1894 (Butlin et. al., 1971, Table 51 p. 494). Investment in deferred deposit receipts paying 4.5 per cent and debentures and stock paying between 4 and 4.5 per cent offered attractive yields if these liabilities could be purchased at a discount to their face value.

It has been possible to calculate the ‘market value’ of the outstanding liabilities of each bank at December of each year by multiplying the figures shown in Appendix C by the published price[13]. The resulting ‘market value’ series, shown in Table 5 (details for individual banks appear in Appendix D), is a weighted average of the individual bank series. This series could be analogous to the value of certificates of deposit and so included as part of monetary aggregates. It is clear that these assets were not as ‘liquid’ as bank deposit liabilities insofar as there was a spread between bid and ask prices. Furthermore, the instability and unpredictability of the means suggests a level of uncertainty about market price (Juttner 1987, pp. 86–87).

Table 5: ‘Market Value’ of Deferred Deposit Receipts and Inscribed Deposit Stock within Australia 1893-1914
Dec. (£ms)
Column 1 Column 2 Column 3 Column 4
‘Face Value’ ‘Market Value’ Ratio: ‘Market Value’ to ‘Face Value’ ‘Net Market Value’
1893 37.897 29.075 0.7672 28.092
1894 32.615 25.443 0.7801 23.733
1895 24.527 19.225 0.7838 17.676
1896 20.929 16.623 0.7943 14.819
1897 17.897 13.021 0.7276 11.074
1898 16.617 12.844 0.7728 10.725
1899 13.948 10.728 0.7691 8.443
1900 12.012 9.398 0.7824 6.878
1901 10.955 7.808 0.7127 5.556
1902 10.564 6.829 0.6464 4.793
1903 10.172 7.062 0.6943 4.951
1904 9.927 7.044 0.7096 4.868
1905 9.290 7.061 0.7601 4.624
1906 8.984 7.590 0.8448 4.889
1907 8.601 6.898 0.8020 4.105
1908 8.420 6.387 0.7586 3.621
1909 8.125 6.303 0.7758 3.471
1910 6.651 5.807 0.8731 2.790
1911 6.187 5.386 0.8705 2.335
1912 5.907 4.799 0.8124 1.923
1913 5.779 4.599 0.7958 1.652
1914 5.234 3.961 0.7568 1.181

Source:
Column 1. ‘Face Value’ – Table 3.
Column 2. ‘Market Value’ – Appendix D.
Column 4. ‘Net Market Value’ less market value of ‘other liabilities’

While no data on the volume of trades are available, it is likely that the market was ‘thin’. Accepting these caveats, including this estimate of the value of the ‘certificates of deposit’ to the currency in the hands of the public and the unencumbered deposits held by trading banks within Australia would provide a generous upper bound for estimate of the stock of money from 1893 until 1914. The resulting series is shown in Table 6.

Table 6: Estimates of Revised Monetary Aggregates, M2 and M3 Including ‘Market Value’ of Deferred Deposit Receipts and Stock 1890–1914
Dec. (£ms)
M2* M3*
1890 108.387 118.439
1891 108.232 119.572
1892 108.014 120.385
1893 85.003 99.332
1894 84.680 100.381
1895 87.952 105.346
1896 89.882 107.869
1897 87.129 106.653
1898 85.181 104.816
1899 91.371 113.282
1900 94.452 118.699
1901 95.244 121.460
1902 96.709 124.538
1903 95.682 124.417
1904 95.538 125.506
1905 102.438 132.876
1906 111.722 144.282
1907 117.911 154.292
1908 118.596 158.869
1909 123.004 165.813
1910 136.417 182.126
1911 152.655 204.772
1912 156.598 215.869
1913 153.669 219.387
1914 166.124 236.546

Source: Adding ‘market value’ given in Table 5 less the market value of ‘other liabilities’ to M2 and M3 as shown in Table 4.

Even this upper bound calculation of M2* and M3* suggest a more severe contraction in monetary aggregates than the series produced by Schedvin. M2* contracted by 23 per cent in 1893 while M3* fell by 17.5 per cent over the same year. Once again, there was little difference between this and the other series with respect to the number of years elapsed before the earlier peaks were matched in nominal terms.

Footnotes

For an account of the market see AIBR (1893), pp. 858, p. 1088 and p. 1101 and (1895), pp. 81, pp. 149–150 and p. 163. Official List of the Stock Exchange of Melbourne held in University of Melbourne Archives. [12]

Price data was collected as quoted for December of each year where possible. If no quotation was available for that month the nearest date on either side was used. Prices were drawn from those quoted in the monthly stock exchange list in the AIBR and the annual survey of the Stock Exchange of Melbourne as reported in the Argus and Age newspapers. [13]