RDP 2018-03: The Effect of Zoning on Housing Prices

1. Introduction

Some government policies, which we will refer to as zoning, restrict the supply of housing. Examples include minimum lot sizes, maximum building heights and planning approval processes. Although these restrictions may confer benefits, they also raise the price of housing. This paper attempts to quantify the effect of zoning on housing prices in Australia's four largest cities.

Anecdotal evidence suggests that zoning can have a huge effect on land values. For example, a 363 hectare site in Wyndam Vale (40 km west of Melbourne) increased in value from $120 million to $400 million following its rezoning from rural to residential (Schlesinger and Tan 2017). Examples like this are common – Appendix A provides more. Such large increases in values as a result of zoning changes are inconsistent with the view that a physical shortage of land itself is the main cause of high land values and housing prices – and instead point towards a high ‘shadow price’ of government permission to build dwellings as a likely explanation. It is difficult, however, to gauge how representative these anecdotes are, or to analyse how they change over time or place.

A natural approach to this issue might be to examine the effects of differences in zoning regulations. However, for reasons we discuss in Section 2, that approach is not appropriate for estimating zoning's overall effect on prices. Instead, we follow the approach of Glaeser and Gyourko (2003) and Glaeser, Gyourko and Saks (2005), which involves comparing property prices to the marginal cost of supply. For detached houses, this means decomposing property values into the cost of the structure and the value of physical land at that location, with the remainder being attributable to zoning restrictions.

To illustrate, and to preview our results, we estimate that the average Sydney house, valued at $1.16 million in 2016, represents a $395,000 structure on a $765,000 block of land.[1] However, the reason land is expensive is not because it is physically scarce. Hedonic regressions indicate that home owners do not value it, as land, especially highly. Specifically, they value land as worth about $400 a square metre on the margin, or $277,000 for the average Sydney block. This ‘marginal’ or ‘physical’ value of land represents the opportunity cost of extra land, as judged by what people are prepared to pay for it.[2] This is $489,000 less than its market value. This difference represents what home owners need to pay for the right to have a dwelling at that location, or the cost of ‘administrative’ scarcity. The academic literature refers to this difference as the ‘zoning tax’ because the wedge between prices and costs is induced by government-determined scarcity and to draw an analogy with a Pigouvian welfare tax. We, however, use the less-loaded term ‘zoning effect’, which avoids implying that government revenue is involved.

The difference between the average (or market) price and the marginal (or physical) value of land represents an arbitrage opportunity. In the absence of zoning, an investor could purchase properties where the marginal value of land is lower than the average value, subdivide them to create multiple smaller properties, and make a profit. More concretely, excluding the effect of zoning, the marginal Sydney house buyer could have been supplied with an average house for $671,000 – it would have cost $395,000 to build the structure and landowners (existing or potential) would have been prepared to forego the land for $277,000. Instead, buyers needed to pay $1.16 million. The extra $489,000 reflects administrative restrictions. That is, zoning restrictions raised prices 73 per cent above the cost of supply.

This effect is similar but smaller in other cities. We estimate that zoning restrictions raised the average price of detached houses, relative to supply costs, by 69 per cent in Melbourne, 42 per cent in Brisbane and 54 per cent in Perth. As a share of the total price, these contributions are 42 per cent (Sydney), 41 per cent (Melbourne), 29 per cent (Brisbane) and 35 per cent (Perth). Higher-density dwellings require a slightly different approach. As discussed in Section 8, we estimate that zoning restrictions raised average apartment prices, relative to marginal cost, by 85 per cent in Sydney, 30 per cent in Melbourne and 26 per cent in Brisbane.

Figure 1, a standard supply-demand diagram, may help to interpret our estimates. Point A represents a frictionless market, with the number of dwellings equal to QE supplied and demanded at price PE. However, if restrictions limit supply to QMax, the price would rise to PZoning as QMax intersects the demand curve at point B. The gap between what home buyers pay (PZoning) and the marginal cost of supply (PSupply) is our estimate of the zoning effect. This zoning effect or ‘shadow price’ can be thought of as the price a developer would be willing to pay for permission to build one more dwelling at a given location.

Figure 1: Stylised Housing Market with a Binding Quantitative Zoning Constraint
Figure 1: Stylised Housing Market with a Binding Quantitative Zoning Constraint

As this diagram indicates, our focus is narrow and partial equilibrium in nature: specifically, we focus on the effect of zoning on prices under current conditions. While this allows us to answer some important questions about the effect of zoning regulations, there are others that we cannot address. In particular, we do not examine effects on quantities, incomes or other measures. Nor do we examine the benefits of zoning, such as the externalities of congestion and overdevelopment. Our approach does not allow us to estimate the difference in house prices compared with a counterfactual of no zoning restrictions (PE in Figure 1). Estimating this difference would require estimating the slope of demand and supply curves, together with general equilibrium effects. This would be an important exercise for a calculation of welfare costs, but it is beyond the scope of this paper. Kulish, Richards and Gillitzer (2011) address this issue.

Another limitation of our approach is that because we estimate the effect of zoning indirectly, as a residual, any errors in our estimates of the other components of marginal costs will flow through to our estimated zoning effect. This matters because our estimates of costs rest on some assumptions that strike us as reasonable, but are difficult to quantify.

Several government, academic and private sector studies have pointed to restrictive zoning as being an important factor in Australia's high and rising housing prices. These include OECD (2010); Kulish et al (2011); Productivity Commission (2011, 2017); HSAR Working Party (2012); RBA (2014); Senate Economics References Committee (2015); CEDA (2017); Stevens (2017) and Daley, Coates and Wiltshire (2018), among others. Most of those papers that make policy recommendations call for increases in land supply and changes to zoning rules to allow for greater housing density. A problem with that recommendation is that it implicitly weighs benefits against costs, but these are not based on quantitative evidence. This paper tries to partially fill that gap by quantifying the effect of zoning restrictions on housing prices.

Several previous studies have focused on variations in zoning regulations. McIntosh, Trubka and Hendriks (2016, p 52) regress Sydney land values on zoning regulations and numerous other controls, including suburb and distance to transport. They find that rezoning a property from detached housing (a floor space to land area ratio of 0.5) to a 5- to 10-storey apartment block (a floor space to land area ratio of 4) would, on average, increase the value of land by 167 per cent. In an earlier, simpler study, the Centre for International Economics (CIE and ARUP 2012; CIE 2013) finds effects from a number of different types of zoning restrictions. In total, these restrictions are conservatively estimated as imposing a cost of $8 to $16 billion in Sydney, which is small relative to the value of the housing stock. There have been many international studies of variations in regulations; these often find large effects on prices. Gyourko and Molloy (2015), Furman (2015) and Hilber and Vermeulen (2016) provide overviews of this research.

In contrast, Ong et al (2017) examine variations in the number and types of planning controls used by local councils and find they have little effect on housing supply. This may be because, as they discuss (p 50), their planning controls do not reflect variations in zoning or density measures. Instead, their estimates place substantial weight on the number of controls used, including a variety of controls that we would not expect to have a material effect on supply or prices – for example, relating to caravan parks, native vegetation and so on.

In addition to study-specific issues, there are some general limitations with a focus on variations in regulations. First, most of the papers cited above estimate the effects of differences in regulations, whereas we are interested in their overall effect. It is often not the variations in zoning that matter, but their average level. As Kulish et al (2011) discuss, a uniform restriction (for example, a height limit) will have a much larger effect in the city centre than in outlying suburbs. And unchanged restrictions will bind more tightly as demand grows. Second, regulations vary from one jurisdiction to the next, which makes it difficult to compare, aggregate or extend estimates. Third, variations in zoning are often a function of variations in prices, as well as a cause, an issue emphasised by Saiz (2010).

In their literature survey, Gyourko and Molloy (2015) suggest that these difficulties can be avoided by comparing prices to the marginal cost of supply. This is the approach taken by Glaeser and Gyourko (2003) and Glaeser et al (2005), who examine single-family detached dwellings in US metropolitan areas. They find that the wedge between marginal costs and prices is large in markets where narrative evidence suggests zoning restrictions bind tightly (typically big coastal cities) and negligible in others where restrictions are thought to be loose, such as in the south and mid-west. We discuss this approach and apply it to Australia's largest cities in Sections 3, 4 and 5.

Others have already applied this approach elsewhere. Lees (2018) studies cities in New Zealand. Cheung, Ihlanfeldt and Mayock (2009) look at metropolitan areas in Florida and Sunding and Swoboda (2010) examine southern California. In an undergraduate essay, Turnbull (2005) examines the Sydney housing market. These studies all find large effects of zoning for some cities. As we discuss below, we have better data than was available to these researchers. Nevertheless, our estimates are similar.

High-density housing raises different issues and calls for a slightly modified approach. Glaeser et al (2005) compare the market price of apartments in Manhattan to the marginal cost of adding an additional floor to a development. They find a large gap between prices and marginal cost, from which they conclude that regulatory restrictions were responsible for at least half of the price of apartments in Manhattan in the early 2000s. Cheshire and Hilber (2008) apply this approach to commercial property in Europe and find that restrictions on supply increase office rents several fold. We apply this approach to Australia in Section 8.

3. Decomposing Property Values into Dwelling Structure and Land

To estimate the effect of zoning, we consider the cost of a marginal increase in the number and density of dwellings for a given area and given population (hence a reduction in average household size). This means that we do not include the costs involved in increasing the footprint or size of a city, such as provision of extra roads and utilities, as a cost of supplying housing.

We first decompose property values into contributions from land and structures. We have three main sources of information on this, each of which gives broadly similar results (Table 1). Readers who are not interested in the strengths and limitations or calculation of the various measures can take our baseline estimates as given and skip ahead to the next section. Further details are in the Online Appendix (Section 1), available in the supplementary information provided with this paper on the RBA's website.

Perhaps the simplest and most direct approach to splitting land and structure values is to use estimates of land values from state valuers general, who collect estimates for tax purposes. In Australia, land taxes are levied by state and (especially) local governments. These estimates are constructed using sales of vacant lots and improved properties, with the latter adjusted to remove the value of the improvements.

Table 1: Dwelling Structure and Land Value Estimates
Detached houses, 2016
  Perth Brisbane Melbourne Sydney
State valuer general        
Average value of land (per lot, $′000) 399 331 545 663
Average value of existing structures ($′000) 189 211 247 497
ABS Building Activity Survey        
Average value of new structures ($′000) 302 315 306 346
Average value of new structures ($/m2) 1,331 1,325 1,269 1,520
Average value of existing structures ($′000)(a) 241 241 246 314
Industry sources        
Average value of new structures ($/m2) 1,642 1,922 1,604 1,810
Average value of new structures ($′000) 373 457 387 412
Average value of existing structures ($′000)(a) 297 349 311 374
Baseline estimate        
Average value of existing structures ($′000)(b) 242 267 268 395
Average land value (per lot, $′000)(c) 346 275 524 765
Memo items:
Average size of new structures (m2)(d) 227 238 241 227
Average size of existing structures(m2)(e) 180 177 183 194
Average property value ($′000)(f) 588 542 793 1,160

Notes: (a) Adjusted upwards to account for period houses (1, 3, 6 and 7 per cent for Perth, Brisbane, Melbourne and Sydney respectively)
(b) Simple average of existing structure value estimates from each method
(c) Mean sale price from our CoreLogic hedonic regression sample minus our estimate of structure value
(d) Based on completions from the Building Activity Survey in 2015/16 in corresponding state
(e) Based on average floor area sold in 2016 in our CoreLogic hedonic regression sample for each city
(f) Mean sale price from our CoreLogic hedonic regression sample

Sources: ABS; Authors' calculations; CoreLogic; Department of Environment, Land, Water and Planning (Victoria); Department of Natural Resources and Mines (Queensland); Rawlinsons Group (2017); Rider Levett Bucknall (2017); State of New South Wales through the Office of the Valuer General; Western Australian Land Information Authority (Landgate)

The NSW Valuer General provides estimates of land values for individual properties in Sydney, which we match to our sample of sales in 2016. For the other three cities, we use valuer general estimates of land values for detached houses by local government area, from which we construct a city-wide average. Estimates are shown in row 1 of Table 1. For example, the estimated average land value for Sydney for detached houses sold in 2016 is $663,000. The $497,000 difference between this and the average Sydney sale price of $1.16 million represents our first estimate of the average value of structures, shown in row 2 of Table 1.

Valuers general dedicate considerable resources to accurately producing these estimates, and conceptually they are closely aligned with our purposes.[3] However, there is the possibility of downward bias in land value estimates if landowners challenge high estimates of their land value, but not low estimates.[4] Anecdotal reports suggest this bias may be significant. In addition, there are likely to be some small differences in how the estimates are constructed in different states. One advantage of the valuer general estimates is that they are disaggregated by local government area, which we examine in Section 7.

The ABS's Building Activity Survey (BAS) provides estimates of the value of new detached dwelling structures by state. For example, as shown in row 3 of Table 1, our estimate from the BAS of the average cost of building a new house in NSW in 2016 was $346,000.[5] However, we need estimates of the value of existing structures, which will tend to be smaller than the value of new structures, given that house size has increased over time. We account for this by adjusting construction costs in proportion. The average house built in NSW in 2016 was 227 square metres, implying an average construction cost of $1,520 per square metre (row 4). We multiply this construction cost by the average floor space of existing houses (194 square metres) and add a 7 per cent upward adjustment for period houses (discussed in the Online Appendix) to estimate the value of existing house structures of about $314,000 (row 5).

A third source of information on construction costs is provided by Rawlinsons Construction Cost Guide (Rawlinsons Group 2017) and Rider Levett Bucknall's (RLB) ‘Riders Digest 2017’ (Rider Levett Bucknall 2017). These are widely used references in the construction industry that provide estimates for different types of construction projects in different cities. Rawlinsons and RLB report estimates on a cost per square metre basis. As shown in row 6, our estimates from these sources suggest that in Sydney a new house would cost $1,810 per square metre to build. As shown in row 7, this would imply that a new Sydney house would cost $412,000 to build, while replacing the average established Sydney house with one the same size would cost $374,000 (row 8). This method is similar to the approach used by Glaeser et al (2005), who use industry-sourced estimates of construction costs to derive estimates of structure value.

Two difficulties in inferring the value of existing dwellings from new construction costs are allowing for depreciation and renovations and dealing with ‘period houses’. We discuss these in the Online Appendix, Section 1.

The three estimates of construction costs discussed above each have their strengths and weaknesses. However, for our purposes the similarity of the estimates is more important. They range from 27 per cent to 43 per cent of the average Sydney sale price, from 31 to 39 per cent for Melbourne, from 39 to 64 per cent for Brisbane, and from 32 to 51 per cent for Perth. None of the three approaches consistently generates the highest or the lowest estimate. Our estimates contain some outliers. For example, the structure value in Sydney based on valuer general estimates is high relative to other cities and other approaches. The industry-based structure estimate in Brisbane is high relative to the other estimates. We expect that closer examination of the underlying data would narrow these ranges, but this would have little effect on our conclusions and is left for further work.

For purposes of a baseline, we take a simple average of the structure value estimates from each method, shown in Table 1. For Sydney, this means an average structure cost of $395,000 and an average land value of $765,000 given the average sale price of $1.16 million.

The estimates in Table 1 can be compared with other estimates. The annual national accounts estimate that the value of residential land in Australia is approximately twice the value of residential dwelling structures. This is similar to the results in Table 1. Unfortunately, however, the national accounts estimates do not distinguish between detached and high-density dwellings. Moreover, estimates are available at the state but not city level. That said, these data can be useful for evaluating national trends (e.g. Lowe 2015).

The UDIA (2017) report that vacant lots of land sold for an average of $465,000 in Sydney and $237,000 in Melbourne in 2016. These estimates are far below the prices of land in Table 1. This is because most undeveloped land is located on the outskirts of cities and these vacant lots tend to be relatively small.

Urbis (2011) estimates development costs for detached housing on greenfield sites and for apartment blocks on infill sites. These estimates have been emphasised by Hsieh, Norman and Orsmond (2012) and RBA (2014). After allowing for inflation and differences in house size, the Urbis construction cost estimates for detached housing are similar to those in Table 1, which is unsurprising given that they are sourced from Rider Levett Bucknall. Urbis estimates of land costs for detached housing are much lower, reflecting their focus on greenfield developments in outlying suburbs (and the rapid growth in land prices subsequent to their study).

Urbis make explicit allowance for some additional costs that we exclude, most importantly subdivision and infrastructure costs. This reflects their different focus. Whereas they are interested in the cost of converting more land to residential use, we are interested in more intensive use of residential land that is already serviced.[6] A liberalisation of zoning would not directly increase the population or area of a city, so the costs of urban growth are appropriately excluded from our estimates of marginal cost.[7] In any case, these costs are not large, relative to our estimates, and would not change our conclusions. An upper bound on these costs is provided by Urbis's estimates of average costs per dwelling for Sydney greenfield sites: subdivision construction costs were estimated at $47,000 and infrastructure costs (including Section 94 contributions) were $44,000 in 2011. Together these amounted to about 13 per cent of the average Sydney sale price. The Housing Industry Association (2011) and Centre for International Economics (CIE 2011) argue that a large part of the ‘infrastructure charge’ does not reflect genuine costs. These costs are much lower on infill sites and in other cities. The Online Appendix (Section 1) discusses these costs and charges in more detail.

4. Estimating the Physical Value of Land

Having estimated that property prices (particularly in Sydney and Melbourne) largely reflect the high value of land, we turn to the question of why land is so expensive. Our results in this section indicate that home buyers are not prepared to pay an especially large amount for additional land – suggesting that land's scarcity as a physical commodity (at that location) does not account for the high prices we observe. This can be seen from a hedonic regression of house sale prices as follows.

Our focus is on the coefficient b, which represents the marginal value of land (sometimes called the ‘intensive margin’ or the value of physical land), while c is a constant, X is a vector of controls for other characteristics of each property, such as location, number of bedrooms, number of bathrooms and so on and e is a residual. We emphasise that what we call the value of physical land is location-specific, and should be interpreted as what home buyers are prepared to pay for an additional piece of land at a given location. The log-log specification means that physical land is more expensive, on the margin, in locations where prices are high.[8]

We estimate our equation using unit record data of residential property sales. The data are available for purchase from CoreLogic and are discussed in the Online Appendix (Section 2). In brief, we restrict our sample to detached dwellings, and include only the most recent sale of each property. We allocate property sales according to the Greater Capital City Statistical Areas defined by the ABS, which correspond to a very broad area around each city. For example, our Sydney sample extends to the Blue Mountains and Gosford. Our Melbourne sample includes the Mornington Peninsula and Mitchell. Before estimating our equations, we make a number of adjustments to clean the data and remove outliers.[9]

Our regressions control for local geographic characteristics using dummies corresponding to the suburb of each property as provided by CoreLogic. As might be expected, these controls account for a large proportion of the variance in sale prices.[10] We also include quarterly time dummies. We report standard errors allowing for clustering at the local government area level, as there may be geographical correlation within the model residuals due to regional characteristics that we do not control for. White standard errors are much smaller.

We report the results of regressions including different sets of additional control variables. Our small regression includes only a small number of property characteristics that are likely to be the most important, are commonly used in the hedonic house price literature, and have few or no missing values in our sample. Our medium regression includes a number of extra control variables which have few or no missing values in our sample and category dummies in place of the number of bedrooms and bathrooms. Our large regression includes additional control variables for which we do not have data for a substantial portion of our observations. Rather than excluding observations which have missing values for one of these extra variables (around half in 2016, and substantially more for earlier years), we include an indicator dummy for whether an observation has a value recorded or not to control for potential compositional differences between sales with more or less information recorded.[11]

Table 2 summarises the results for each city for 2016, with the full regression results reported in Appendix B. Our results indicate that our small equation can explain most of the variation in (log) sale prices in the data, with additional variables only providing marginal contributions. The coefficient on log land area is estimated quite precisely (reflecting the large number of observations), and is stable across different specifications. The estimated coefficients on the additional control variables seem to have the expected signs and plausible magnitudes (where statistically significant).

Table 2: Hedonic Equation Estimation Results and Physical Value of Land Estimates
2016
  Perth Brisbane Melbourne Sydney
Small equation(a)
Log land area coefficient 0.24 0.22 0.26 0.24
Cluster-robust standard error(b) 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.02
R2 0.75 0.79 0.88 0.87
Medium equation(c)
Log land area coefficient 0.22 0.20 0.24 0.23
Cluster-robust standard error(b) 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.02
R2 0.77 0.81 0.88 0.87
Large equation(d)
Log land area coefficient 0.24 0.21 0.25 0.24
Cluster-robust standard error(b) 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.02
R2 0.81 0.83 0.89 0.88
Number of observations 25,480 35,581 52,177 43,069
Estimated physical value of land (baseline, large equation) ($/m2)(e) 219 129 317 411
Average value of land ($/m2)(f) 540 305 828 1,137

Notes: (a) Controls for number of bedrooms and bathrooms, and includes suburb and quarterly time dummies
(b) Clustered by local government area
(c) As in the small regression, but groups bedrooms and bathrooms into categories, and also controls for number of car spaces and occupant type, as well as flags for swimming pool, air conditioning, ducted heating and scenic views
(d) As in the medium regression, but also controls for log floor area, sale method and year built (sorted into categories) where data are available, and the ratio of the number of bedrooms to bathrooms
(e) Evaluated as the marginal effect of an additional square metre of land for a property with the average land area and average sale price in the sample
(f) Baseline average land value estimate, divided by mean land area

Sources: Authors' calculations; CoreLogic

To interpret our results, consider the estimated coefficient on log land area in our large equation for Sydney of 0.24. This means that, holding other characteristics constant, house prices in a given suburb would be bid up by approximately 0.24 per cent for every 1 per cent increase in land area. For the average Sydney property, with a land area of 673 square metres and a value of $1.16 million, that means an extra 6.73 square metres raises the property value by $2,764 (= $1,160,000 × 0.0024) or $411 a square metre.[12] This contrasts with the average cost of land of $1,137 per square metre. Equivalently, the marginal value to home owners of 673 square metres of land is $276,000, but the block of land costs $765,000.[13] Administrative scarcity means that people have to pay the extra $489,000 above marginal cost for the right to have a structure on that land. As shown in Table 2, similar calculations imply that in Brisbane, Melbourne and Perth the physical value of land is also much less than the average value of land, although the difference is smaller than in Sydney.

5. Zoning Effect Estimates

We now use our estimates to show that zoning restrictions are a major contributor to the cost of housing, and the largest proximate cause of cross-city differences in average house prices.

Table 3 shows the decomposition of average house prices into the three components. The structure and land split from Table 1 is repeated in the first two rows. The third row shows the contribution of land value due to physical scarcity, calculated by multiplying our baseline (large equation) hedonic estimates of the marginal value of land by the average lot size. The fourth row shows the zoning effect, which is the difference between the average land value and the physical land value. These are the paper's central results.

Table 3: Average House Price Decomposition
$′000 (per cent of total), 2016
  Perth Brisbane Melbourne Sydney
Dwelling structure 242 (41) 267 (49) 268 (34) 395 (34)
Land 346 (59) 275 (51) 524 (66) 765 (66)
Physical land 140 (24) 116 (21) 201 (25) 276 (24)
Zoning effect 206 (35) 159 (29) 324 (41) 489 (42)
Total 588 (100) 542 (100) 793 (100) 1,160 (100)
Zoning effect as a percentage of physical input costs 54 42 69 73

Sources: Authors' calculations; CoreLogic

The zoning effect can be expressed as a percentage of the costs of the physical inputs or of the total price. We alternate between the two, depending on the context. We estimate that zoning restrictions raise the price of the average house in Sydney by 73 per cent above the value of the physical inputs (structure and physical land) required to provide it. Corresponding effects are 69 per cent for Melbourne, 42 per cent for Brisbane and 54 per cent for Perth. As a share of total property value, the contribution from zoning is 42 per cent in Sydney, 41 per cent in Melbourne, 29 per cent in Brisbane and 35 per cent in Perth. There are substantial differences between cities, especially in dollar terms, with zoning restrictions adding only $159,000 to the cost of the average house in Brisbane, compared with $489,000 in Sydney.

Estimates of the zoning effect in other countries span a wide range. The effect is estimated to be large in cities with tight restrictions and negligible where building is unrestricted. Our estimates are similar to estimated effects in cities with tight restrictions. For example, Glaeser et al (2005) estimate zoning effects, as a share of total price, for 1998–99 of 53 per cent in San Francisco, 47 per cent in San Jose and 34 per cent in Los Angeles. Cheung et al (2009) estimate zoning effects for 2005 of around 40 per cent for Miami and Orlando, 30 per cent for Tampa and 25 per cent for Jacksonville. Lees (2018) estimates effects of 56 per cent in Auckland, 48 per cent in Wellington and 32 per cent in Christchurch.

In important ways, our estimates are based on better data than was available to these earlier studies. Where other estimates often rely on small samples, our regressions have sample sizes in the tens of thousands. Where some other studies use self-assessed property values to estimate the hedonic value of land, we use actual sale prices. Where other studies only have industry construction cost estimates, we are able to use valuer general and ABS estimates also.

In contrast to the effect of zoning restrictions, differences in dwelling structure values across cities account for relatively little of the variation in average sale prices. Our estimates of average structure value for Australia are broadly similar (at 2017 exchange rates) to estimates for New Zealand in Lees (2018), but almost 50 per cent higher than estimates for the United States from Glaeser and Gyourko (2018) (see the Online Appendix, Section 1).

We estimate that the value of physical land for the average house in Sydney is higher than for Melbourne, and substantially higher than for Brisbane or Perth. However, as a share of average house prices these estimates are similar (between 21 and 25 per cent), and high compared with overseas estimates. Physical land accounted for between 4 and 9 per cent of average house value in Auckland, Wellington and Christchurch based on the numbers reported in Lees (2018). Estimates in Glaeser and Gyourko (2003) imply that physical land accounted for between 3 and 12 per cent of total land value in the six cities with the highest average house prices in their study. The relatively high physical land value that we find for Australian cities may reflect geographical constraints facing the expansion of these cities (e.g. coasts and national parks), combined with high demand reflecting population growth and low real interest rates.

In decomposing property values into the structure, physical land and zoning, some readers have asked whether ‘location’ – as, for example, measured by our suburb dummies – should also be allowed for, given that this is an attribute that buyers pay highly for. To the extent that land at a location is physically scarce, the value of location will already be captured in our physical land term. To the extent that land at a location is scarce because of administrative restrictions, it shows up in the zoning effect.

5.1 Robustness of Our Hedonic Estimates

A central feature of our results is that the marginal value of land is less than the average value. Our method for estimating the contribution of zoning restrictions to house prices is based on this difference between marginal and average value, so sensitivity of our marginal land value estimates to the functional form of our hedonic regression would be a concern.

Our baseline logarithmic specification is simple, but fits our data well. It is fairly common in the literature, being used by previous hedonic house price applications, in both Australia (e.g. Hansen 2006; CoreLogic 2017) and overseas (e.g. Glaeser et al 2005). Our estimates of the log land area coefficient are not sensitive to the inclusion of control variables (as shown in Table 2 above) and are stable across time.

More importantly, our estimates of marginal land value are insensitive to a range of more flexible functional forms and with estimating regressions at a disaggregated level, although our baseline estimate for Melbourne is slightly lower than estimates from other methods. Table 4 shows some illustrative examples. See the Online Appendix (Section 2) for more detail on these alternatives. Cheung et al (2009) and Sunding and Swoboda (2010) also find that estimates of the zoning effect are robust to various regression specifications and levels of geographic aggregation.

Table 4: Physical Land Value Estimates from Alternative Specifications
Marginal value of land at mean sale price and lot size, 2016, $ per square metre
  Perth Brisbane Melbourne Sydney
Greater Capital City-level regressions
Baseline (log-log, all controls) 219 129 317 411
Including (log land area) squared 226 138 319 422
Replacing log land area with cubic land area terms 292 159 374 460
Weighted average from disaggregated regressions
LGA-level (log-log, all controls) 203 143 337 442
Clusters of SA2s (linear-linear, all controls) 235 102 364 404

Sources: ABS; Authors' calculations; CoreLogic

In contrast, some researchers have used more restrictive specifications, such as a linear-linear specification of sale prices and land area. However, this specification has the implausible implication that land is equally valued everywhere in the city (whereas in the log-log specification it is proportional to property value). We find even lower estimates for marginal land value using this functional form.[14]

Our hedonic estimates of the marginal value of land are similar to other hedonic housing studies of Australian cities.

Hansen (2006, p 16) reports regressions of log house prices using Australian Property Monitors data. His coefficient estimates on log land area are similar to ours for Sydney (0.28) and Melbourne (0.19). However, he reports a much larger coefficient of 0.39 for Brisbane. One cause of this difference could be that Hansen's regressions are run on only a sub-sample of 1 per cent of Brisbane sales due to missing values for a range of characteristics. In addition, Hansen's sample includes townhouses as well as detached houses, and controls for property zoning.

Syed, Hill and Melser (2008) construct hedonic house price indices for different regions of Sydney from 2001 to 2006 using regressions of logged sale prices on a range of characteristics including quadratic terms for lot size, and lot size interacted with a number of other variables. Their estimated quadratic lot size coefficients for 2006 (p 57) imply that a 1 per cent increase in lot size (for a property with a lot size of 635 square metres – the mean in our sample of sales in 2006) would increase sale prices by 0.21 per cent, similar to our estimate of 0.24.

Frino et al (2010) report regressions of log house prices in Australian cities for the period 2005 to 2009. They report coefficients on log land area that are substantially lower than our findings: 0.10 for Sydney, 0.08 for Melbourne, 0.13 for Brisbane, and 0.16 for Perth. This appears to be because they control for location at a much less granular level than we do (our coefficient estimates are similar if we include dummies for the ABS Statistical Area Level 4 of each property instead of the suburb).

5.2 Sensitivity of Our Zoning Effect Estimates to Inputs

Our zoning effect estimates are calculated indirectly, and so depend on our estimates of the other components of the cost of housing. We now consider how sensitive our zoning effect estimates are to changes in our estimates of structure value and physical land value. Overall, our baseline estimates are reasonably robust.

Table 5 reports the estimated zoning effect calculated using each of our methods for estimating structure value individually, instead of the average. Our sense is that although different approaches lead to noticeable variations in the precise estimate of the zoning effect, these are not large enough to alter our qualitative conclusions.

Table 5: Zoning Effect Estimates with Different Structure Values
Zoning effect as a per cent of average house prices
  Perth Brisbane Melbourne Sydney
Baseline estimate 35 29 41 42
State valuer general 44 40 43 33
ABS Building Activity Survey 35 34 44 49
Industry sources 26 14 35 44

Sources: ABS; Authors' calculations; CoreLogic; Department of Environment, Land, Water and Planning (Victoria); Department of Natural Resources and Mines (Queensland); Rawlinsons Group (2017); Rider Levett Bucknall (2017); State of New South Wales through the Office of the Valuer General; Western Australian Land Information Authority (Landgate)

Table 6 reports the estimated zoning effect using the estimates of physical land value from the alternative specifications reported in Table 4. Some of these specifications suggest a slightly higher physical value of land than our baseline estimate, but our zoning effect estimates are not very sensitive to these differences.

Table 6: Zoning Effect with Different Physical Land Estimates
Zoning effect as a per cent of average house prices
  Perth Brisbane Melbourne Sydney
Greater Capital City-level regressions
Baseline (log-log, all controls) 35 29 41 42
Including (log land area) squared 34 28 41 41
Replacing log land area with cubic land area terms 27 24 36 39
Weighted average from disaggregated regressions
LGA-level (log-log, all controls) 37 27 39 40
Clusters of SA2s (linear-linear, all controls) 33 34 37 43

Sources: ABS; Authors' calculations; CoreLogic

5.3 Other Issues

Our estimates take the value of physical land as exogenous. However, zoning restrictions that reserve land for industrial or agricultural uses increase the physical scarcity of residential land and hence raise its market value. This implies that our estimates of the zoning effect may understate the total impact of zoning restrictions on the cost of housing.

In contrast, any factor that increases the wedge between sale prices and our estimate of supply costs will tend to boost our estimate of the effect of zoning. One example is time delays between an increase in housing demand and when new housing supply comes online, which could temporarily boost prices. If these delays reflect regulatory policies, it is reasonable to interpret them as part of the zoning effect. However, the persistence of zoning effects documented in Section 6 suggests that simple delays are not as important as long-lasting obstacles. To the extent that delays reflect genuine physical/market constraints, considering estimates of the zoning effect over a multi-year period, as we do in Section 6, should mitigate this concern.

Another example is if developers are able to exert market power to earn supernormal profits, then sale prices of residential properties will be higher than the marginal costs that they face. However, the market for developing and building residential dwellings is generally considered to be highly competitive, with low barriers to entry and a large number of firms (Glaeser et al 2005; Minifie, Chisholm and Percival 2017; Lees 2018).[15] Glaeser and Gyourko (2018) show that in US cities without tight zoning restrictions, prices are usually close to costs.

Perhaps the most important concern about our estimates is the possibility that we have underestimated costs. As noted in Section 3, we exclude subdivision and infrastructure costs, which are substantial for greenfield developments but not for increasing housing density. We also exclude adjustment costs, specifically when demolition of old structures is necessary for a change in land use. When demolition is necessary, the cost of supply is not only the cost of land and new structures, but also includes the acquisition cost of partially-depreciated structures.

We have excluded adjustment costs for two reasons. First, they are highly variable and difficult to quantify. Second, house prices are determined on the margin, and marginal adjustment costs are often low. Australia's cities have low average density and heterogeneous housing stocks.[16] So underdeveloped blocks of land and heavily depreciated structures, for which adjustment costs are low, are widespread. Substantial increases in density – for example, from large-lot detached dwellings to high-rise apartments – reduce adjustment costs by spreading them across many new dwellings. Moreover, increasing the density of new developments does not incur a marginal adjustment cost. Adjustment costs are more likely to be material in already developed areas, and it is possible that this (along with the cost of consolidating land parcels for high-rise development) may further contribute to higher property values in inner-city areas, relative to the city fringe.

6. Decomposing Average House Prices over Time

Figure 2 shows a decomposition of property prices back to 1999. To extend our estimates of structure value back in time, we adjust the estimates from Table 1 by movements in the producer price index (PPI) – output of house construction series for each city's corresponding state, and by movements in the average floor area of houses sold in each city.[17] To estimate the value of physical land over time, we estimate separate regressions for each year back to 1999.

Given that housing supply takes time to respond to developments in demand (even in the absence of zoning restrictions), looking at the zoning effect over a period of a few years may reduce concerns that a gap between prices and costs reflects temporary supply shortages or delays.[18]

In all four cities, our estimate of the zoning effect increased rapidly as a share of average house value over the early 2000s, alongside rapidly rising house prices. Subsequent to this initial rise, the patterns across cities diverged somewhat. The increase in our zoning effect estimates over this time period are likely due to existing zoning restrictions becoming more binding as demand has risen, rather than a meaningful change in the restrictions themselves.

Our estimates suggest that while structure values have increased in all four cities since the early 2000s, they have declined substantially as a share of average house prices. Estimated physical land values have increased more rapidly over time in Melbourne and Sydney than in Brisbane and Perth, but have accounted for a relatively small share of the divergence in average house prices between the four cities over the period.

Figure 2: House Price Decomposition
By city, mean
Figure 2: House Price Decomposition

Sources: ABS; Authors' calculations; CoreLogic

Our data extend earlier in time than shown in Figure 2. However, the contribution of land becomes so small that property values fall within the range of our estimates of construction costs in Brisbane and Melbourne. Estimates for early years would be decomposing measurement error. Indeed, our earliest estimates of the zoning effect in Brisbane and Melbourne are slightly negative. We suspect this arises because the industry-based approach to estimating structure value is too high for these cities. Notwithstanding this, our decomposition suggests that zoning restrictions were not a material constraint on housing development in these cities at this time – unlike in Sydney, where the zoning effect is estimated to have been around 20 per cent of average sale prices, even in 2000. This also shows that our methodology does not result in substantial estimates of the zoning effect in every place and at every point in time.

7. Geographic Distribution of Zoning Effects within Cities

Figures 3–6 show estimates of the zoning effect for the average property in local government areas (LGAs). We split property prices into structure values and land values in each LGA, using the CoreLogic data on property prices and the valuer general estimates for land values for each LGA (as this allows structure value to vary across LGAs for reasons other than just floor area).[19] We then estimate physical land values by running separate hedonic regressions for each LGA of the form of our large regression in Section 4.[20] Our estimate of the zoning effect by LGA is then the remaining portion of land value not accounted for by the physical value.

If zoning restrictions were relatively uniform in nature across a city, we would expect the zoning effect to be largest (in dollar terms) where underlying demand to develop land is the highest, which is likely to be close to the CBD, or perhaps in coastal areas (Kulish et al 2011). Our results are broadly consistent with this expected pattern. Figures 3–6 also indicate a high degree of spatial correlation in our estimates – neighbouring LGAs tend to have similar zoning effects. Spatial correlation could reflect similarity in zoning restrictions and demand to develop land, but it could also arise because supply restrictions in one location spill over to neighbouring locations that are close substitutes.

Section 3 of the Online Appendix contains maps of the zoning effect as a share of average property value in each LGA. Patterns in these maps are less clear, as there is considerable variation in structure values and physical land values (mostly reflecting average lot sizes) between neighbouring LGAs.[21] The Online Appendix also contains maps showing physical land values by LGA. As Fujita, Krugman and Venables (1999) discuss, the demand for land increases with proximity to the city centre.

We have not investigated how, or if, certain characteristics of LGAs systematically contribute to the patterns we observe (e.g. distance from CBD/coast, population density, demographics, minimum lot sizes, maximum building heights), but this could be a possible avenue for future research.

Figure 3: Sydney Zoning Effect Estimate by Local Government Area
Average, 2016, $′000
Figure 3: Sydney Zoning Effect Estimate by Local Government Area

Note: The 2011 edition of the ABS's LGA boundaries are used for Sydney

Sources: ABS; Authors' calculations; CoreLogic

Figure 4: Melbourne Zoning Effect Estimate by Local Government Area
Average, 2016, $′000
Figure 4: Melbourne Zoning Effect Estimate by Local Government Area

Sources: ABS; Authors' calculations; CoreLogic

Figure 5: Brisbane Zoning Effect Estimate by Local Government Area
Average, 2016, $′000
Figure 5: Brisbane Zoning Effect Estimate by Local Government Area

Sources: ABS; Authors' calculations; CoreLogic

Figure 6: Perth Zoning Effect Estimate by Local Government Area
Average, 2016, $′000
Figure 6: Perth Zoning Effect Estimate by Local Government Area

Note: Peppermint Grove LGA was combined with Mosman Park LGA for estimation purposes

Sources: ABS; Authors' calculations; CoreLogic

8. Apartment Prices and Marginal Costs

This section compares apartment prices to the marginal cost of supply.[22] The RBA's liaison with industry contacts has highlighted poor availability of suitable development sites (which is likely in large part due to zoning restrictions that do not allow high-density development in many areas) and the time and complexity of obtaining planning approvals as the most significant supply-side factors for new apartment construction in Australia (Shoory 2016).

As noted earlier, Glaeser et al (2005) argue that in Manhattan, the marginal cost of supplying apartments is equal to the construction costs associated with adding an additional storey to a new development. Although land is required to build an apartment block, this is a fixed cost – there is no marginal land cost involved with building higher on a given block. Glaeser et al then infer the presence of zoning restrictions by comparing apartment prices to these marginal construction costs.

Although Australia's large cities have ample space in urban areas that could be converted from other uses to apartment buildings, for simplicity we follow Glaeser et al by focusing only on the cost of building additional storeys.[23] We rely on estimates of construction costs per square metre for apartment buildings of different heights provided by Rider Levett Bucknall (2017) and the CoreLogic unit record dataset to calculate average sale prices. A detailed discussion of our data and methodology is in the Online Appendix (Section 4).

For this exercise, we consider the marginal cost of constructing a 20-storey apartment building relative to a 10-storey building. RBA liaison evidence and Daley et al (2018, p 50) indicate that buildings in this range are representative of a large share of the apartment market in major cities. We make an allowance for other marginal costs associated with increasing the size of an apartment project, such as providing common areas, professional fees and an entrepreneurial return. Finally, we adjust costs for earlier time periods using the corresponding state PPI – output of other residential building construction series, and scale to the average size of apartments sold in each city during the corresponding period (e.g. 79 square metres in Sydney in 2016).

Our analysis of the Rider Levett Bucknall estimates suggests that, on average, it would cost about $470,000 to add an extra apartment to a 10–20 storey building in Sydney in 2016. This is the marginal cost; the average variable cost is $435,000. Although comparison can be difficult, alternative data sources point to similar, or somewhat smaller, estimates. For example, estimates by the CIE (2011) suggest a typical 100 square metre Sydney apartment costs $438,000 to build (adjusted to 2016 dollars using the appropriate PPI), whereas our estimates imply that such an apartment would cost $552,000 (average cost in a 10–20 storey building). Discussions with industry participants tend to suggest average construction costs cluster around $300,000 to $500,000, with more dispersion in estimates of fees, margins and overheads.

Our analysis of the CoreLogic dataset indicates that the average Sydney apartment sold for $870,000 in 2016.[24] This is about $400,000 (85 per cent) more than our estimate of marginal cost, representing 46 per cent of the sale price. As with detached houses, this $400,000 wedge represents an arbitrage opportunity. The reason that builders do not exploit it is that they are prohibited from doing so by zoning regulations.[25] See Moore (2012) for an example. Similar analysis, summarised in Table 7, implies that zoning restrictions added $120,000 to the cost of apartments in Melbourne and $110,000 in Brisbane. Our estimate of the zoning contribution for Sydney is broadly in line with the findings of Glaeser et al (2005), who found that zoning accounted for around half of the cost of apartments in Manhattan in 2002, but smaller than Lees (2018), who found that zoning accounted for around 70 per cent of the cost of apartments in Auckland.

Table 7: Apartment Cost and Prices
2016
  Brisbane Melbourne Sydney
Marginal cost, per square metre of floor area ($/m2) 4,953 5,731 5,985
Average floor area of apartments sold (m2) 87 68 79
Marginal cost, per apartment ($′000) 429 390 471
Average apartment sale price ($′000) 539 510 870
Zoning effect ($′000) 110 120 399
Zoning effect (% of marginal cost) 26 30 85

Sources: ABS; Authors' calculations; CoreLogic; Rider Levett Bucknall (2017)

If scarcity of government permission to develop apartments in desirable locations is pushing up their price, then we would expect the value or ‘shadow price’ of development rights to be capitalised into the prices of sites with such permissions. Discussions with developers and several examples in Appendix A are consistent with this. Site prices are often quoted as a price ‘per unit’, and our sense is that our estimated wedges from zoning of $400,000 per unit in Sydney and $120,000 in Melbourne are broadly in line with these prices.[26]

Figure 7 plots average apartment sale prices against our estimates of marginal costs for Sydney, Melbourne and Brisbane over time.

Figure 7: Apartment Price, Construction Cost and Zoning Effect Estimates
By city, mean
Figure 7: Apartment Price, Construction Cost and Zoning Effect Estimates

Note: The zoning effect for each city is the average sale price minus estimated construction cost

Sources: ABS; Authors' calculations; CoreLogic; Rider Levett Bucknall (2017)

Over the period from 1999 to 2006, we estimate that the gap between sale prices and marginal costs was low and broadly stable in all three cities, although the gap was slightly larger on average in Sydney ($121,000 versus $60,000 in Brisbane and $47,000 in Melbourne). This analysis suggests that zoning was not an important constraint on apartment development in Brisbane or Melbourne over this period.

In both Melbourne and Brisbane, marginal costs were broadly unchanged over the period from 2006 to 2016. However, average sale prices rose slightly, and so the gap between sale prices and costs has been somewhat higher in recent years. In Sydney, costs rose slightly over the same period, but apartment sales prices increased much more sharply. As a result, the gap between prices and costs – the zoning effect – has increased substantially in Sydney over the past decade.

Our estimates of apartment costs involve several assumptions and are somewhat uncertain. They are not comprehensive, but we believe they are representative of a large share of the apartment market. Moreover, the RBA's discussions with developers suggest that our overall numbers are in line with widely used rules of thumb in the industry. The results do not seem to be sensitive to moderate variations in the assumptions. More direct data would be useful. However, we would be surprised if it were to indicate a very different contribution of zoning to apartment prices.

9. Discussion

Overall, our results suggest that development restrictions (interacting with increasing demand) have contributed materially to the significant rise in housing prices in Australia's largest cities since the late 1990s, pushing prices substantially above the supply costs of their physical inputs. Although we find that differences in the value of dwelling structures and the physical value of land account for some of the variation in average housing prices across the four cities we examine, our zoning effect estimates account for the majority of the differences. We also find evidence of a large gap opening up between apartment sale prices and construction costs over recent years, especially in Sydney. This suggests that zoning constraints are also important in the market for high-density dwellings.

We estimate that zoning restrictions raise detached house prices by 73 per cent of marginal costs in Sydney, for example. We emphasise that this is not the amount that house prices would fall in the absence of zoning. As discussed in our introduction, that would require estimating supply and demand responses, which is beyond our scope. We also note that physical land costs are higher in Australian cities (particularly Sydney) than overseas. So even if zoning restrictions were relaxed, housing in Australia would remain expensive relative to cities where zoning is permissive and land is less physically scarce.

Ideally, policy with respect to zoning would reflect a weighing of the benefits and costs. Our analysis contributes to such a decision by quantifying some important costs. These should be offset against the benefits from zoning, such as offsetting the negative externalities of intensified or uncoordinated development. Gyourko and Molloy (2015) discuss the evidence on these issues and conclude that the overall efficiency losses from constraints on residential development may be large, with costs outweighing benefits by a substantial margin. Subsequent research (Albouy and Ehrlich 2017) supports this conclusion. However, both these studies note that the benefits of most forms of zoning regulations are difficult to quantify.

As Furman (2015) discusses, zoning regulations have some important effects that go beyond those we quantify. As they become more binding and contribute to increases in property prices, they represent a wealth transfer from future home buyers to current home owners (see, for example, the discussion in Lowe (2015)). They also result in higher rents as the supply of housing is constricted. Both of these factors may increase inequality. La Cava (2016) and Glaeser and Gyourko (2018) emphasise rising house values in supply constrained markets as a driver of changes in the distribution of wealth and income in the United States. Murray and Frijters (2015) argue that many of the benefits seem to accrue to those with political connections and can be dissipated in rent-seeking.

Development restrictions also reduce the responsiveness of the housing stock to changes in preferences and relative prices. This can ‘lock in’ an increasingly obsolete urban structure (Kelly, Weidmann and Walsh 2011). Cheshire, Hilber and Koster (2018) find that planning restrictions lead to a substantial misallocation of housing resources in England. Perhaps more importantly, these restrictions prevent labour from being allocated to where it is most productive. Estimates for the United States suggest these effects are large (Hseih and Moretti 2015; Glaeser and Gyourko 2018; Herkenhoff, Ohanian and Prescott 2018). Zoning restrictions reduce the elasticity of housing supply, making housing prices more responsive to changes in underlying demand. As Glaeser, Gyourko and Saiz (2008) document, this means that house prices are more variable than otherwise, with potentially negative consequences for financial and price stability.

If housing demand continues to grow, as seems likely, then existing zoning restrictions will bind more tightly and place continuing upward pressure on housing prices. Policy changes that make zoning restrictions less binding, whether directly (e.g. increasing building height limits) or indirectly, via reducing underlying demand for land in areas where restrictions are binding (e.g. improving transport infrastructure), could reduce this upward pressure on housing prices.

Appendix A: Examples of Zoning Effects on Land and Property Values

Some examples of reports of large effects from zoning changes, compiled from a few hours googling:

  • Michael Coco, a real estate agent, estimates that properties on the south side of Derby St, Penrith, zoned for two-storey developments, are worth $600,000 while those on the north side, zoned for six storeys, are worth $1 million (Jones 2016). Some properties on the north side reportedly doubled in value overnight when the rezoning was announced.
  • Kulish et al (2011, p 30) cite estimates that the inclusion of agricultural land with the urban growth boundary of Melbourne raises its value from below $35,000 a hectare to above $300,000 a hectare. They also describe (fn 23) how the relaxation of zoning restrictions on property in St Leonards in Sydney raised the land value from $3 million to $14 million.
  • According to Moran (2005, p 26), ‘Soon after the [Melbourne's] Urban Growth Boundary was introduced, land brought inside it, say, around Whittlesea, was selling at some $600,000 per hectare where previously before the Boundary de facto rezoned it as housing it cost $150,000–200,000 per hectare'.
  • Inner West Council (2016, p 27) report that rezoning a 1,000 square metre block of land in Sydney's inner west from industrial to eight-storey apartments changes the land value from $2 million to $10.7 million.
  • Murray and Frijters (2015) report that the rezoning of 13,000 hectares in south-east Queensland from rural to residential between 2008 and 2010 raised land values by $700 million.
  • Wallace Zagoridis, a developer, estimates that the value of his $8 million site was halved when Ku-ring-gai Council reduced the permitted height of his project from seven to five storeys (Moore 2012).
  • Chong (2015) lists large profits being made on former industrial sites that have been rezoned for residential development in Sydney. For example, the Goodman group made profits of $400 million to $600 million; the Dexus Property group expected profits of $90 million. A 6.9 hectare site near Erskineville, purchased for $16 million was sold for $350 million after rezoning. Two sites in Rosebery initially valued at $96 million were sold for $190 million. Consolidating nine houses in St Leonards, valued at up to $18 million, in a site for 200 apartments, raised the land value to $55 million.
  • Land prices doubled in the Montague precinct of Fishermans Bend in Melbourne after the industrial area was rezoned to allow for residential development without mandatory height limits (Johanson 2012).
  • Zhou (2017) reports that sites in Melbourne with approved plans and permits for medium-density development are selling for a significant premium, with approvals adding several hundreds of thousands of dollars to property values.

Appendix B: Detailed 2016 Detached Housing Regression Results

Table B1: Sydney Hedonic Equation Estimation Results
  Small Medium Large
Log land area 0.241 (0.016) 0.226 (0.016) 0.238 (0.018)
Bedrooms 0.049 (0.003)    
Bathrooms 0.091 (0.004)    
3 bedrooms (baseline: 1–2 bedrooms)   0.049 (0.010) 0.059 (0.012)
4 bedrooms   0.111 (0.011) 0.120 (0.017)
5 bedrooms   0.149 (0.011) 0.161 (0.020)
6+ bedrooms   0.146 (0.013) 0.168 (0.027)
2 bathrooms (baseline: 1 bathroom)   0.059 (0.005) 0.030 (0.016)
3 bathrooms   0.145 (0.008) 0.099 (0.024)
4 bathrooms   0.218 (0.014) 0.158 (0.032)
5+ bathrooms   0.312 (0.025) 0.231 (0.037)
1 car space (baseline: 0 spaces)   0.069 (0.010) 0.059 (0.009)
2 car spaces   0.106 (0.009) 0.091 (0.009)
3+ car spaces   0.121 (0.010) 0.109 (0.009)
Swimming pool   0.047 (0.005) 0.045 (0.005)
Air conditioned   0.029 (0.004) 0.021 (0.003)
Ducted heating   0.023 (0.005) 0.017 (0.005)
Scenic view   0.047 (0.011) 0.044 (0.011)
Occupant: renter (baseline: owner-occupier)   −0.014 (0.004) −0.011 (0.004)
Occupant: govt – rented   −0.051 (0.008) −0.053 (0.007)
Occupant: govt – other   0.160 (0.057) 0.177 (0.058)
Bedroom to bathroom ratio     −0.011 (0.009)
Dummy: has floor area data     −0.158 (0.021)
Log floor area     0.030 (0.004)
Dummy: has year built data     0.037 (0.010)
Built 1930–1949 (baseline: built before 1930)     −0.017 (0.007)
Built 1950–1979     −0.063 (0.010)
Built 1980–1999     −0.055 (0.011)
Built 2000–2009     0.029 (0.010)
Built after 2009     0.066 (0.010)
Dummy: has sale method data     0.046 (0.008)
Sold prior to auction (baseline: private treaty)     0.004 (0.002)
Sold at auction     0.011 (0.004)
Sold after auction     0.016 (0.004)
2016:Q2 dummy 0.022 (0.003) 0.024 (0.003) 0.023 (0.003)
2016:Q3 dummy 0.060 (0.003) 0.065 (0.003) 0.063 (0.003)
2016:Q4 dummy 0.098 (0.003) 0.107 (0.004) 0.104 (0.004)
R2 0.867 0.874 0.879
Regression standard error 0.201 0.196 0.192
Observations 43,069 43,069 43,069

Notes: Cluster-robust standard errors (clustered by LGA) in parentheses; all three specifications include suburb dummies

Sources: Authors' calculations; CoreLogic

Table B2: Melbourne Hedonic Equation Estimation Results
  Small Medium Large
Log land area 0.255 (0.013) 0.237 (0.013) 0.253 (0.013)
Bedrooms 0.060 (0.004)    
Bathrooms 0.103 (0.006)    
3 bedrooms (baseline: 1–2 bedrooms)   0.055 (0.010) 0.057 (0.012)
4 bedrooms   0.131 (0.011) 0.122 (0.016)
5 bedrooms   0.162 (0.013) 0.149 (0.021)
6+ bedrooms   0.127 (0.016) 0.129 (0.024)
2 bathrooms (baseline: 1 bathroom)   0.091 (0.005) 0.070 (0.014)
3 bathrooms   0.176 (0.010) 0.142 (0.023)
4 bathrooms   0.259 (0.017) 0.205 (0.030)
5+ bathrooms   0.291 (0.034) 0.214 (0.038)
1 car space (baseline: 0 spaces)   0.027 (0.008) 0.030 (0.007)
2 car spaces   0.064 (0.008) 0.062 (0.008)
3+ car spaces   0.076 (0.010) 0.077 (0.010)
Swimming pool   0.053 (0.010) 0.050 (0.009)
Air conditioned   0.015 (0.003) 0.013 (0.002)
Ducted heating   0.011 (0.002) 0.008 (0.002)
Scenic view   0.066 (0.016) 0.064 (0.016)
Occupant: renter (baseline: owner-occupier)   −0.034 (0.004) −0.030 (0.004)
Occupant: govt – rented   0.199 (0.026) 0.201 (0.034)
Occupant: govt – other   −0.042 (0.047) 0.026 (0.067)
Bedroom to bathroom ratio     −0.004 (0.008)
Dummy: has floor area data     −0.283 (0.029)
Log floor area     0.056 (0.006)
Dummy: has year built data     0.081 (0.013)
Built 1930–1949 (baseline: built before 1930)     −0.051 (0.012)
Built 1950–1979     −0.104 (0.013)
Built 1980–1999     −0.115 (0.014)
Built 2000–2009     −0.034 (0.015)
Built after 2009     0.007 (0.018)
Dummy: has sale method data     0.013 (0.005)
Sold prior to auction (baseline: private treaty)     0.004 (0.003)
Sold at auction     −0.009 (0.005)
Sold after auction     0.024 (0.004)
2016:Q2 dummy 0.025 (0.003) 0.027 (0.003) 0.026 (0.003)
2016:Q3 dummy 0.058 (0.003) 0.062 (0.004) 0.060 (0.004)
2016:Q4 dummy 0.101 (0.004) 0.109 (0.005) 0.105 (0.005)
R2 0.878 0.884 0.891
Regression standard error 0.180 0.175 0.170
Observations 52,177 52,177 52,177

Notes: Cluster-robust standard errors (clustered by LGA) in parentheses; all three specifications include suburb dummies

Sources: Authors' calculations; CoreLogic

Table B3: Brisbane Hedonic Equation Estimation Results
  Small Medium Large
Log land area 0.222 (0.011) 0.201 (0.013) 0.214 (0.016)
Bedrooms 0.065 (0.002)    
Bathrooms 0.126 (0.008)    
3 bedrooms (baseline: 1–2 bedrooms)   0.052 (0.005) 0.064 (0.010)
4 bedrooms   0.123 (0.007) 0.121 (0.013)
5 bedrooms   0.183 (0.005) 0.176 (0.015)
6+ bedrooms   0.162 (0.016) 0.167 (0.022)
2 bathrooms (baseline: 1 bathroom)   0.100 (0.010) 0.065 (0.013)
3 bathrooms   0.207 (0.016) 0.154 (0.026)
4 bathrooms   0.253 (0.016) 0.188 (0.028)
5+ bathrooms   0.346 (0.024) 0.270 (0.034)
1 car space (baseline: 0 spaces)   0.017 (0.009) −0.003 (0.005)
2 car spaces   0.058 (0.010) 0.028 (0.007)
3+ car spaces   0.085 (0.017) 0.060 (0.008)
Swimming pool   0.065 (0.005) 0.065 (0.004)
Air conditioned   0.050 (0.004) 0.037 (0.002)
Ducted heating   0.056 (0.006) 0.050 (0.005)
Scenic view   0.076 (0.013) 0.071 (0.013)
Occupant: renter (baseline: owner-occupier)   −0.043 (0.004) −0.036 (0.004)
Occupant: govt – rented   0.001 (0.032) 0.045 (0.048)
Occupant: govt – other   0.012 (0.042) 0.016 (0.035)
Bedroom to bathroom ratio     −0.010 (0.006)
Dummy: has floor area data     −0.248 (0.014)
Log floor area     0.046 (0.003)
Dummy: has year built data     0.045 (0.005)
Built 1930–1949 (baseline: built before 1930)     −0.006 (0.005)
Built 1950–1979     −0.069 (0.003)
Built 1980–1999     −0.049 (0.006)
Built 2000–2009     0.034 (0.007)
Built after 2009     0.097 (0.012)
Dummy: has sale method data     0.071 (0.013)
Sold prior to auction (baseline: private treaty)     0.000 (0.003)
Sold at auction     0.007 (0.013)
Sold after auction     0.017 (0.012)
2016:Q2 dummy 0.011 (0.003) 0.009 (0.003) 0.008 (0.003)
2016:Q3 dummy 0.029 (0.006) 0.026 (0.004) 0.027 (0.004)
2016:Q4 dummy 0.045 (0.003) 0.042 (0.002) 0.045 (0.001)
R2 0.794 0.814 0.828
Regression standard error 0.192 0.182 0.175
Observations 35,581 35,581 35,581

Notes: Cluster-robust standard errors (clustered by LGA) in parentheses; all three specifications include suburb dummies

Sources: Authors' calculations; CoreLogic

Table B4: Perth Hedonic Equation Estimation Results
  Small Medium Large
Log land area 0.243 (0.008) 0.224 (0.009) 0.238 (0.010)
Bedrooms 0.061 (0.005)    
Bathrooms 0.156 (0.009)    
3 bedrooms (baseline: 1–2 bedrooms)   0.051 (0.010) 0.036 (0.017)
4 bedrooms   0.106 (0.014) 0.075 (0.028)
5 bedrooms   0.160 (0.013) 0.128 (0.034)
6+ bedrooms   0.081 (0.022) 0.072 (0.043)
2 bathrooms (baseline: 1 bathroom)   0.127 (0.008) 0.065 (0.027)
3 bathrooms   0.273 (0.014) 0.168 (0.038)
4 bathrooms   0.316 (0.035) 0.200 (0.057)
5+ bathrooms   0.149 (0.113) 0.037 (0.110)
1 car space (baseline: 0 spaces)   −0.025 (0.016) −0.046 (0.014)
2 car spaces   0.042 (0.017) −0.012 (0.015)
3+ car spaces   0.076 (0.018) 0.022 (0.015)
Swimming pool   0.064 (0.005) 0.065 (0.004)
Air conditioned   0.048 (0.008) 0.021 (0.005)
Ducted heating   −0.005 (0.005) −0.001 (0.005)
Scenic view   0.110 (0.023) 0.101 (0.021)
Occupant: renter (baseline: owner-occupier)   −0.036 (0.006) −0.020 (0.005)
Occupant: govt – rented   −0.027 (0.022) 0.027 (0.024)
Occupant: govt – other   −0.142 (0.028) −0.149 (0.031)
Bedroom to bathroom ratio     −0.004 (0.015)
Dummy: has floor area data     −0.535 (0.077)
Log floor area     0.109 (0.015)
Dummy: has year built data     0.333 (0.026)
Built 1930–1949 (baseline: built before 1930)     −0.028 (0.019)
Built 1950–1979     −0.107 (0.022)
Built 1980–1999     −0.100 (0.022)
Built 2000–2009     0.015 (0.026)
Built after 2009     0.080 (0.026)
Dummy: has sale method data     0.092 (0.008)
Sold prior to auction (baseline: private treaty)     0.003 (0.003)
Sold at auction     0.048 (0.024)
Sold after auction     0.006 (0.016)
2016:Q2 dummy −0.012 (0.005) −0.011 (0.005) −0.015 (0.004)
2016:Q3 dummy −0.020 (0.005) −0.017 (0.005) −0.025 (0.005)
2016:Q4 dummy −0.028 (0.006) −0.019 (0.006) −0.027 (0.005)
R2 0.751 0.773 0.812
Regression standard error 0.216 0.207 0.188
Observations 25,480 25,480 25,480

Notes: Cluster-robust standard errors (clustered by LGA) in parentheses; all three specifications include suburb dummies

Sources: Authors' calculations; CoreLogic

References

Albouy D and G Ehrlich (2017), ‘Housing Productivity and the Social Cost of Land-Use Restrictions’, NBER Working Paper No 18110, rev December.

CEDA (Committee for Economic Development of Australia) (2017), Housing Australia, Research report, Committee for Economic Development of Australia, Melbourne.

Cheshire PC and CAL Hilber (2008), ‘Office Space Supply Restrictions in Britain: The Political Economy of Market Revenge’, The Economic Journal, 118(529), pp F185–F221.

Cheshire PC, CAL Hilber and HRA Koster (2018), ‘Empty Homes, Longer Commutes: The Unintended Consequences of More Restrictive Local Planning’, Journal of Public Economics, 158, pp 126–151.

Cheung R, K Ihlanfeldt and T Mayock (2009), ‘The Regulatory Tax and House Price Appreciation in Florida’, Journal of Housing Economics, 18(1), pp 34–48.

Chong F (2015), ‘The Property Players Cashing in on Sydney's Rezoned Land’, The Australian online, 15 April, viewed January 2018. Available at <http://www.theaustralian.com.au/business/business-spectator/the-property-players-cashing-in-on-sydneys-rezoned-land/news-story/a76e65f878b8fd2fc17e55f1039b4174>.

CIE (Centre for International Economics) (2011), ‘Taxation of the Housing Sector’, Final report prepared for the Housing Industry Association, September.

CIE (2013), ‘Reform of the NSW Planning System’, Final report prepared for NSW Planning and Infrastructure, October.

CIE and ARUP (2012), ‘Costs and Benefits of Alternative Growth Scenarios for Sydney’, Final report prepared for NSW Planning and Infrastructure, August.

CoreLogic (2017), ‘Residential Property Index Series’, August, viewed January 2018. Available at <https://www.corelogic.com.au/sites/default/files/2017-09/CoreLogicHPISeriesMethodologyAug2017.pdf>.

Daley J, B Coates and T Wiltshire (2018), Housing Affordability: Re-imagining the Australian Dream, Grattan Institute, Melbourne.

Ellis L (2013), ‘Housing and Mortgage Markets: The Long Run, the Short Run and the Uncertainty in Between’, Address to the Citibank Property Conference, Sydney, 23 April.

Fox R and R Finlay (2012), ‘Dwelling Prices and Household Income’, RBA Bulletin, December, pp 13–22.

Frino A, A Lepone, V Mollica and A Vassallo (2010), ‘The Impact of Auctions on Residential Sale Prices: Australian Evidence’, Australasian Accounting, Business and Finance Journal, 4(3), pp 3–22.

Fujita M, P Krugman and AJ Venables (1999), The Spatial Economy: Cities, Regions, and International Trade, The MIT Press, Cambridge.

Furman J (2015), ‘Barriers to Shared Growth: The Case of Land Use Regulation and Economic Rents’, Keynote address given at ‘Data, Demand and Demographics: A Symposium on Housing Finance’, Co-hosted by the Urban Institute and CoreLogic, Washington DC, 20 November.

Glaeser EL and J Gyourko (2003), ‘The Impact of Building Restrictions on Housing Affordability’, Economic Policy Review, 9(2), pp 21–39.

Glaeser EL and J Gyourko (2018), ‘The Economic Implications of Housing Supply’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(1), pp 3–30.

Glaeser EL, J Gyourko and A Saiz (2008), ‘Housing Supply and Housing Bubbles’, Journal of Urban Economics, 64(2), pp 198–217.

Glaeser EL, J Gyourko and R Saks (2005), ‘Why is Manhattan So Expensive? Regulation and the Rise in Housing Prices’, The Journal of Law & Economics, 48(2), pp 331–369.

Gyourko J and R Molloy (2015), ‘Regulation and Housing Supply’, in G Duranton, JV Henderson and W Strange (eds), Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics: Volume 5B, Handbooks in Economics, North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 1289–1337.

Hansen J (2006), ‘Australian House Prices: A Comparison of Hedonic and Repeat-Sales Measures’, RBA Research Discussion Paper No 2006-03.

Herkenhoff KF, LE Ohanian and EC Prescott (2018), ‘Tarnishing the Golden and Empire States: Land-Use Restrictions and the U.S. Economic Slowdown’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 93, pp 89–109.

Hilber CAL and W Vermeulen (2016), ‘The Impact of Supply Constraints on House Prices in England’, The Economic Journal, 126(591), pp 358–405.

Hill RJ and M Scholz (2014), ‘Incorporating Geospatial Data in House Price Indexes: A Hedonic Imputation Approach with Splines’, University of Graz, Graz Economics Papers 2014-05.

Hodges J (2015), ‘Questions on Notice following Australian Bureau of Statistics’ Submission to the House of Representatives Home Ownership Inquiry’, 5.2 Supplementary to Submission 5, Submission to the House of Representatives Standing Committee on Economics Inquiry into Home Ownership, 24 July. Available at <https://www.aph.gov.au/DocumentStore.ashx?id=652af284-b3ee-4840-9833-de62a89bdf8d&subId=353206>.

Housing Industry Association (2011), ‘The Taxation Burden on the Australian New Housing Sector’, Summary. Available at <https://hia.com.au/-/media/HIA-Website/Files/Media-Centre/Submissions/2011/Tax-Forum-Submission-Background.ashx?la=en&hash=A0A2DFB9CB843F967A696F4DFB81238C01FC07AC>.

HSAR (Housing Supply and Affordability Reform) Working Party (2012), ‘Housing Supply and Affordability Reform’, Report to the Council of Australian Governments, September.

Hseih C-T and E Moretti (2015), ‘Housing Constraints and Spatial Misallocation’, NBER Working Paper No 21154, rev May 2017.

Hsieh W, D Norman and D Orsmond (2012), ‘Supply-Side Issues in the Housing Sector’, RBA Bulletin, September, pp 11–19.

Inner West Council (2016), ‘Position Paper: Best Practice in Value Capture’, rev March 2017. Available at <https://www.innerwest.nsw.gov.au/ArticleDocuments/296/Best%20Practice%20in%20Value%20Capture.pdf.aspx>.

Johanson S (2012), ‘Developers in the Zone on New Industrial Landscape’, The Sydney Morning Herald online, 5 December, viewed January 2018. Available at <http://www.smh.com.au/business/property/developers-in-the-zone-on-new-industrial-landscape-20121204-2at78.html>.

Jones M (2016), ‘Council's Decision Makes Some Families Richer Overnight’, The Daily Telegraph online, 10 November, viewed January 2018. Available at <http://www.dailytelegraph.com.au/newslocal/penrith-press/councils-decision-makes-some-families-richer-overnight/news-story/017a15215e95003a0bb319a32f47cc54>.

Kelly J-F, B Weidmann and M Walsh (2011), The Housing We'd Choose, Grattan Institute Report No 2011-5, Gratton Institute, Melbourne.

Kulish M, A Richards and C Gillitzer (2011), ‘Urban Structure and Housing Prices: Some Evidence from Australian Cities’, RBA Research Discussion Paper No 2011-03.

La Cava G (2016), ‘Housing Prices, Mortgage Interest Rates and the Rising Share of Capital Income in the United States’, RBA Research Discussion Paper No 2016-04.

Lees K (2018), ‘Quantifying the Costs of Land Use Regulation: Evidence from New Zealand’, University of Canterbury Department of Economics and Finance Working Paper No 1/2018.

Lowe P (2015), ‘National Wealth, Land Values and Monetary Policy’, 54th Shann Memorial Lecture, Perth, 12 August.

McIntosh J, R Trubka and B Hendriks (2016), ‘Transit and Urban Renewal Value Creation: Hedonic Price Modelling Assessment of Sydney's Key Transit and Transit-Oriented Urban Renewal Investments (2000–2014)’, May, LUTI Consulting and Mecone Planning.

Minifie J, C Chisholm and L Percival (2017), Competition in Australia: Too Little of a Good Thing?, Grattan Institute Report No 2017-12, Gratton Institute, Melbourne.

Moore M (2012), ‘Fury at Council's Timely Rezoning Plan’, The Sydney Morning Herald online, 10 August, viewed January 2018. Available at <http://www.smh.com.au/nsw/fury-at-councils-timely-rezoning-plan-20120809-23x5a.html>.

Moran A (2005), ‘Prices and Planning: The State of the Housing Industry’, Institute of Public Affairs Review, 57(3), pp 24–27.

Murray CK and P Frijters (2015), ‘Clean Money in a Dirty System: Relationship Networks and Land Rezoning in Queensland’, Institute for the Study of Labor, IZA Discussion Paper No 9028.

NSW Ombudsman (2005), Improving the Quality of Land Valuations Issued by the Valuer General: A Special Report to Parliament under s31 and s 26 of the Ombudsman Act 1974, NSW Ombudsman, Sydney.

OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) (2010), OECD Economic Surveys: Australia 2010, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Ong R, T Dalton, N Gurran, C Phelps, S Rowley and G Wood (2017), Housing Supply Responsiveness in Australia: Distribution, Drivers and Institutional Settings, AHURI Final Report No 281, Australian Housing and Urban Research Institute Limited, Melbourne.

Productivity Commission (2011), Performance Benchmarking of Australian Business Regulation: Planning, Zoning and Development Assessments, Volume 1, Research Report, Productivity Commission, Canberra.

Productivity Commission (2017), Shifting the Dial: 5 Year Productivity Review, Inquiry Report No 84, Productivity Commission, Canberra.

Rawlinsons Group (2017), Rawlinsons Construction Cost Guide For Housing, Small Commercial and Industrial Buildings Edition 25, Rawlhouse Publishing, Perth.

RBA (Reserve Bank of Australia) (2014), ‘Submission to the Inquiry into Affordable Housing’, Submission to the Senate Economics References Committee Inquiry into Affordable Housing, February.

Rider Levett Bucknall (2017), ‘Riders Digest 2017: Sydney, Australia’, 45th Edition.

Saiz A (2010), ‘The Geographic Determinants of Housing Supply’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(3), pp 1253–1296.

Schlesinger L and S-L Tan (2017), ‘China's Country Garden Pays $400m for Future Melbourne Suburb’, Australian Financial Review online, 10 July, viewed January 2018. Available at <http://www.afr.com/real-estate/residential/vic/chinas-country-garden-pays-400m-for-future-melbourne-suburb-20170710-gx85mq>.

Senate Economics References Committee (2015), Out of Reach? The Australian Housing Affordability Challenge, (Chairs, M Bishop December 2013–June 2014; S Dastyari July 2014–May 2015), Senate Economics References Committee, Canberra.

Shoory M (2016), ‘The Growth of Apartment Construction in Australia’, RBA Bulletin, June, pp 19–26.

Stevens G (2017), ‘Housing Affordability: Report to the Premier’, 22 May. Available at <https://www.nsw.gov.au/improving-nsw/projects-and-initiatives/first-home-buyers/housing-affordability-report-to-the-premier/>.

Sunding DL and AM Swoboda (2010), ‘Hedonic Analysis With Locally Weighted Regression: An Application to the Shadow Cost of Housing Regulation in Southern California’, Regional Science & Urban Economics, 40(6), pp 550–573.

Syed I, RJ Hill and D Melser (2008), ‘Flexible Spatial and Temporal Hedonic Price Indexes for Housing in the Presence of Missing Data’, University of New South Wales School of Economics Discussion Paper No 2008/14.

Turnbull A (2005), ‘Why is Housing so Expensive in Sydney?’, Honors Thesis (Economics), Harvard University, March.

UDIA (Urban Development Institute of Australia) (2017), ‘State of the Land 2017’, April. Available at <http://www.udia.com.au/news/2017-state-of-the-land>.

Urbis (2011), ‘National Dwelling Cost Study: Prepared for the National Housing Supply Council’, Commissioned by the Department of Sustainability, Environment, Water, Population, and Communities. Available at <https://treasury.gov.au/publication/national-dwelling-costs-study/>.

Valuation Services (2017), ‘Rating and Taxing Valuation Procedures Manual’, Version 7.1.1, Property NSW.

Zhou C (2017), ‘Home Owners Boost Their Property Values without Doing Anything but Paperwork’, domain.com.au, 1 April, viewed January 2018. Available at <https://www.domain.com.au/news/home-owners-boost-their-property-values-without-doing-anything-but-paperwork-20170330-gv8740/>.

CoreLogic Disclaimers

This Report contains data, analytics, statistics and other information supplied by RP Data Pty Ltd trading as CoreLogic Asia Pacific (CoreLogic) and its third party/licensors (CoreLogic Data).

© Copyright 2017. RP Data Pty Ltd trading as CoreLogic Asia Pacific (CoreLogic) and its licensors are the sole and exclusive owners of all rights, title and interest (including intellectual property rights) subsisting in the CoreLogic Data. All rights reserved.

The CoreLogic Data provided in this publication is of a general nature and should not be construed as specific advice or relied upon in lieu of appropriate professional advice.

While CoreLogic uses commercially reasonable efforts to ensure the CoreLogic Data is current, CoreLogic does not warrant the accuracy, currency or completeness of the CoreLogic Data and to the full extent permitted by law excludes all loss or damage howsoever arising (including through negligence) in connection with the CoreLogic Data.

Australian State Disclaimers

Where the CoreLogic Data has been compiled with data supplied under licence from an Australian State government supplier, the following State disclaimers apply in conjunction with CoreLogic Disclaimers:

Queensland Data

Based on or contains data provided by the State of Queensland (Department of Natural Resources and Mines) 2017. In consideration of the State permitting use of this data you acknowledge and agree that the State gives no warranty in relation to the data (including accuracy, reliability, completeness, currency or suitability) and accepts no liability (including without limitation, liability in negligence) for any loss, damage or costs (including consequential damage) relating to any use of the data. Data must not be used for direct marketing or be used in breach of the privacy laws.

South Australian Data

A 2017 Copyright in this information belongs to the South Australian Government and the South Australian Government does not accept any responsibility for the accuracy or completeness of the information or its suitability for purpose.

New South Wales Data

Contains property sales information provided under licence from the Land and Property Information (‘LPI’). RP Data Pty Ltd trading as CoreLogic is authorised as a Property Sales information provider by the LPl.

Victorian Data

The State of Victoria owns the copyright in the Property Sales Data and reproduction of that data in any way without the consent of the State of Victoria will constitute a breach of the Copyright Act 1968 (Cth). The State of Victoria does not warrant the accuracy or completeness of the Property Sales Data and any person using or relying upon such information does so on the basis that the State of Victoria accepts no responsibility or liability whatsoever for any errors, faults, defects or omissions in the information supplied.

Western Australian Data

Based on information provided by and with the permission of the Western Australian Land lnformation Authority (2017) trading as Landgate.

Australian Capital Territory Data

The Territory Data is the property of the Australian Capital Territory. No part of it may in any form or by any means (electronic, mechanical, microcopying, photocopying, recording or otherwise) be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted without prior written permission. Enquiries should be directed to:

Director, Customer Services ACT Planning and Land Authority GPO Box 1908 Canberra ACT 2601.

Tasmanian Data

This product incorporates data that is copyright owned by the Crown in Right of Tasmania. The data has been used in the product with the permission of the Crown in Right of Tasmania. The Crown in Right of Tasmania and its employees and agents:

  1. give no warranty regarding the data's accuracy, completeness, currency or suitability for any particular purpose; and
  2. do not accept liability howsoever arising, including but not limited to negligence for any loss resulting from the use of or reliance upon the data.

Base data from the List © State of Tasmania http://www.thelist.tas.gov.au

Footnotes

To provide context for international readers, the mean annual household disposable income in Australia was $97,000 in 2015/16 (based on the ABS Survey of Income and Housing). Fox and Finlay (2012) discuss internationally consistent comparisons of housing prices and incomes. [1]

Although the value of physical land is low relative to the sale price, it is high in Sydney relative to other Australian cities. Moreover, physical land values in Australian cities are higher than in some overseas cities, a point we discuss in Section 4. [2]

The NSW Valuer General (Valuation Services 2017) provides a 225 page manual describing procedures for land valuation. [3]

A 2005 report (NSW Ombudsman 2005) documented cases of conservative valuations being applied in some areas, but these issues may have since been addressed. [4]

Industry sources suggest that construction costs are typically higher outside of capital cities. Building approvals data are available at a more disaggregated regional level, but are likely to be more volatile (Hodges 2015). [5]

In technical terms, they hold density or factor proportions constant and vary the scale of production. For an examination of the effect of zoning, it is appropriate to hold the scale constant and vary density. [6]

Of course, increased housing supply in one locality would encourage migration to that area. But changes in zoning policy would not directly affect national population so there would be offsetting infrastructure savings elsewhere. For a given population, average infrastructure costs often decrease as density rises, in which case these ‘costs’ would be negative. [7]

We will later demonstrate that our results are robust to a range of plausible alternative hedonic regression specifications. [8]

For example, we exclude houses with more than 2 acres of land in line with Glaeser et al (2005) in order to reduce a possible source of downward bias in our hedonic estimate of land value. [9]

Hill and Scholz (2014) find postcode dummies can account for the vast majority of geospatial variance in the data, due to the relatively narrow definition of postcodes in Australian cities. We use CoreLogic's suburb classifications, which are more narrowly defined than postcodes, but this choice has minimal quantitive effect on our results. [10]

Running the same regression but dropping these observations with missing values has no statistically significant impact on the coefficient of interest (log land area). [11]

Here we follow Glaeser and Gyourko (2003) and Glaeser et al (2005) by evaluating the estimated elasticity from our log-log regression at the mean house price and lot size of our sample, because we seek to decompose mean house prices. Possible alternatives include evaluating the elasticity at the median house price and lot size, or at the mean of logged house prices and logged lot sizes (both of which imply slightly lower estimates for the physical value of land per square metre). [12]

A home owner with diminishing marginal utility would value the entire block at more than the valuation of marginal changes in land size. However, the marginal valuation represents the opportunity cost, or what a developer would need to pay to acquire the land from existing owners for an additional property. A general equilibrium analysis of zoning would consider the effects of home buyers moving along their individual demand curves for land (in the absence of zoning, average lot sizes would likely decrease in high-demand locations as developers increased density), but this outside our scope. [13]

Some researchers include more complicated geospatial information in their hedonic housing models. We experimented with including various factors such as the distance to the CBD, schools, the coast, or railway stations in our regressions, but these had almost no effect on the estimated marginal value of land (likely due to the inclusion of suburb dummies). Specifications that controlled for the average sale price of nearby properties resulted in marginally lower estimates of the hedonic value of land. [14]

Concerns have been raised about the practice of ‘land banking’ pushing up the prices of potential greenfield development sites. However, there is no clear evidence of widespread delays caused by speculative behaviour, and reforming zoning arrangements would likely reduce the time taken for lots to be released for sale and increase competition (HSAR Working Party 2012). [15]

As noted by Ellis (2013), Australian cities are less dense than the cities of any other sizeable country. [16]

Changes in these state PPI series are almost identical to changes in the corresponding capital city CPI new dwelling series, but for technical and conceptual reasons are slightly more appropriate for our use here. We also adjust for the introduction of GST. [17]

Although if the housing market (as an asset market) is forward looking, then expectations of a supply response should offset this to a large degree. [18]

As shown in Table 5, valuer general structure estimates imply a higher zoning effect estimate for Brisbane and Perth and lower for Sydney than would an average of the three valuation approaches. [19]

One difference is that we include sales from both 2015 and 2016 to estimate our hedonic equation, as the sample size for some LGAs was very small using a single year, making estimation of the coefficients difficult. However, we apply the estimated log land area coefficient only to the average sale price and land area of houses sold in 2016. [20]

Sunding and Swoboda (2010) argue that the ‘correct’ level of aggregation is the metropolitan area, because although different localities within the area have different regulations, if households are mobile then the zoning effect across the area will tend to equalise. [21]

We do not provide estimates for Perth owing to the low share of apartments in its dwelling stock. [22]

The lowest marginal cost way of supplying apartments could involve purchasing more land and building up fewer storeys, because the marginal cost of constructing apartments is an increasing function of building height due to the need to employ more expensive construction methods. This could mean that our estimates of the cost of supplying apartments are overstated. [23]

New apartments sold for somewhat more. Because we are using construction costs, we are likely to be overstating replacement value for apartments due to depreciation (renovations are less likely to provide a positive offset than in the case of detached dwellings). [24]

To the extent that planning regulations increase construction costs (rather than creating a wedge between costs and prices), for instance through prescriptive building design and materials requirements, then this effect of regulation on prices will not be captured in our estimates. [25]

The fact that site prices are commonly quoted in per unit terms, rather than in terms of the land area of the site, itself seems to be an indication that a physical scarcity of land is not the main factor driving high site prices. [26]